Journal of Economic Issues, March 2002
v36 i1 p79(28)
A tale of four CARICOM
countries. Winston H. Griffith.
Full Text: COPYRIGHT 2002 Association for Evolutionary
Economics
Less developed countries depend to a great extent on the more
developed countries for growth and development. They depend on the
more developed countries to purchase most of the output of their
principal products and services--sugar and bananas, for example, the
two principal CARICOM (Caribbean
Community) (1) agricultural commodity exports, are produced
primarily for sale in preferential markets of the more developed
countries--and also for inflows of foreign direct investment. This
dependence is due not only to structural characteristics, such as
the smallness of their economies, but also to the path dependence of
colonial institutions that ensured colonies produced goods the
colonizing countries could not produce at home.
But products and services demanded by the more developed
countries today may not be demanded by them tomorrow, the global
trading environment may change, and the conditions that make a
country attractive to the foreign investor today may make the same
country unattractive tomorrow. As the environment changes, less
developed countries must adjust their production structures and
supportive institutions to ensure continued growth and development.
Thorstein Veblen (1899, 133) said, "Institutions are products of the
past process, are adapted to past circumstances, and are therefore
never in full accord with the requirements of the present." He was
implying that, unless they change to suit the new environment,
institutions will slow the process of economic growth and
development. John Dunning (2000, 27) said that "determinants such as
the quality and cost of natural resources and semi-skilled labor are
being replaced by factors such as the availability of a supportive
and sophisticated physical and human infrastru cture." Hence, less
developed countries that created institutions for an earlier period
to attract foreign direct investment when natural resources and
unskilled labor played an important role in production processes
will have great difficulty attracting foreign manufacturing firms in
the new global environment if those institutions created in an
earlier period do not change to suit the new environment.
Institutions may be defined as "prescribed patterns of correlated
behavior" and, as Walter Neale (1987, 1195) noted, they are not
independent of one another. As one changes, others must also change.
Dunning's observation thus suggests that less developed countries
that depend on foreign manufacturing firms to help promote growth
and development must, in addition to other things, create a pool of
highly skilled labor to attract such foreign manufacturing firms.
They will also need highly skilled labor to ensure that their
indigenous manufacturing industries are competitive now that other
less developed countries are liberalizing their trade regimes. To
create a pool of highly skilled labor, governments in less developed
countries will have to restructure their educational systems and
place a greater emphasis on mathematics, engineering, the natural
sciences, and computer science. Furthermore, given the ease with
which capital in the new global economy can move to locations where
skilled and unskilled labor ar e available at competitive prices,
trade unions in less developed countries will be forced to adopt a
less confrontational approach in their dealings with foreign firms
whose workers they have organized.
If institutions adjust quickly to a changing environment, growth
and development will occur more rapidly than if institutions adjust
slowly. However, C. E. Ayres (1962) reminded us that the speed at
which institutions adjust depends on the strength of ceremonialism.
Ceremonialism is present in all societies, but it is more strongly
rooted in less developed countries than in more developed countries.
In any society some activities carry more status than others,
although they possess no technological competence, and by their very
character they are unable to promote structural transformation. But
they carry such an aura of respectability, which members of society
seek, and they are so embedded in the national conscience that any
policy that has the consequence of lowering their status is fiercely
resisted. The struggle between ceremonialism and the forces
promoting economic and social transformation is present in all
societies, and the development of a society depends on whether the
forces of economic and soci al transformation can overcome
ceremonialism.
This article examines the economic performances of four CARICOM countries from about 1970 to 1997. It
does not seek to explain the performances of these countries by
showing how economies did or did not behave according to some
postulate based on given assumptions. It argues that, if they change
one of their major institutions to achieve a certain policy
objective, governments must also change supportive institutions or
they will not attain their objective. The article also argues that
the better economic performance of the Barbadian economy was due to
its ability to exploit economic opportunities that emerged in a
changing global environment when its leading traditional export
industry was facing an uncertain future. Moreover, Barbadian trade
unions entered into an alliance with the government and supported
its austerity measures during the country's deepest post--World War
II recession. This alliance helped the government to successfully
resist the demands of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to
devalu e the currency, which, given the characteristics of the
Barbadian economy, would have worsened economic and social
conditions, as happened in CARICOM
countries that devalued their currencies.
The article begins by discussing the production structure of
CARICOM countries. It then seeks to
explain why Barbados had a better economic performance than the
other countries.
Production Structure
The present-day production structure of CARICOM countries is a continuation of the
production structure imposed on colonies by colonizing countries.
Colonizing countries ensured that the colonial production structure
was complementary to theirs. (2) As a result, agricultural resources
in CARICOM countries were virtually used
for producing commodities for export to colonizing countries while
CARICOM countries were forced to import
most of their food from the colonizing countries. Colonial
industrial production was neglected and so were the financial and
educational systems necessary to support industrial production. And
as a result, colonizing countries supplied their colonies with most
of the manufactures the latter demanded. Colonial production did not
create many backward and forward linkages, the foreign investor
provided much of the capital for colonial investment, and an
indigenous technological capability was markedly absent. These
features of colonial economies--weak agricultural and manufacturing
sect ors, heavy dependence on the foreign investor, and reliance on
extra-regional sources for a preponderance of food and manufactured
goods--persist in post-colonial CARICOM.
CARICOM is not among that small group of
countries that have been able to break out of the retarding
influence of path dependence created by colonial institutions.
As table 1 shows, agriculture's contribution to gross domestic
product (GDP) in CARICOM countries is low
except in Guyana, where its contribution was about 36.4 percent in
1997. In the other three countries it is less than 10 percent. Sugar
and bananas are the principal agricultural commodities produced in
the region. (3) They are produced primarily for export under
preferential arrangements to the markets of the more developed
countries. Protecting an industry may sometimes redound to the
long-run benefit of a country, but it may also be harmful. Veblen
warned that
If any portion or class of society is sheltered from the action
of the environment in any essential respect, that portion of the
community, or that class, will adapt its views and scheme of life
more tardily to the altered general situation; it will in so far
tend to retard the process of social transformation. (1899, 134)
Existing preferential trading arrangements between CARICOM countries and the more developed
countries reinforce the debilitating path dependence created by
colonial institutions, and they have slowed the transformation of
CARICOM agriculture. Assured a market for
their exports, CARICOM sugar and banana
producers have not shown much inclination to diversify production by
introducing new crops, which can lead to the emergence of agro-based
industries and the creation of greater backward and forward
linkages. Furthermore, they receive for their exports to
preferential markets prices much higher than those on the world
market, and this is a disincentive to try to achieve price
competitiveness. According to Sir Alister McIntyre (October 24,
2000), the average cost of producing sugar in the Caribbean is
US$535 per tonne compared with US$266 in the Pacific and US$340 in
Africa. He also said that the average cost of producing bananas in
Jamaica is about US$391, whereas it is US$291 in Colombia, US$179 in
Costa Rica, and US$161 in Ecuador.
Some government policies, too, intended to help the traditional
agricultural export sector, have the unintended consequence of
reinforcing the path dependence that slows the transformation of
CARICOM agriculture. Prime Minister Owen
Arthur of Barbados, in an exchange with the host of a Barbadian
call-in radio talk show, "Guttaperk," said, "[T]he Government [of
Barbados] this year is under a commitment to pay BD$ 19.5 million to
service the debt of the sugar industry. If we do not pay the sugar
industry's bill ..., the industry will collapse" [Weekend Nation
1999, 3].(4) One reason the government of Barbados gives subvention
to an inefficient sugar industry is that the sugar industry employs
about 4,000 workers; and, in a small nation with strong democratic
traditions, the sudden unemployment of such a large number of
persons may create much social and political unrest and bring about
the downfall of the government.
Another reason the government gives subvention to the sugar
industry is that sugar exports are an important source of foreign
exchange. For example, the value of sugar exports in 1998 was about
US$28.6 million (Central Bank of Barbados 1999, 174). The government
of Barbados sometimes sells the entire sugar output in the European
Union (EU) market and imports sugar. (5) Governments whose countries
depend heavily on banana production for growth and development are
forced to support their inefficient banana industries for similar
reasons. But since they know that they can depend on governments to
give them subvention, CARICOM sugar and
banana producers will have less incentive to try to achieve
competitiveness.
 Jamaica
produces bananas and coffee for extra-regional markets. Bananas, the
more important crop, are sold in the EU market. Like the sugar
industry, the Jamaican banana industry makes an important
contribution to the local economy. For example, Jamaican banana
export earnings during the first eleven months of 1997 were US$43.4
million (Caribbean Development Bank 1997, 37). The importance of the
banana industry to the Jamaican economy is evident from the
government's strong opposition to the ruling by the World Trade
Organization (WTO) that the EU banana import-regime discriminates
against bananas from non-ACP (African, Caribbean, and Pacific)
countries and that the EU must liberalize banana imports. The
adoption of a liberal banana import-regime by the EU is a threat to
the viability of the Jamaican banana industry, which is nor
internationally competitive and which will have difficulty adjusting
to a more open trading environment. (6)
CARICOM countries have an agricultural
sub-sector consisting of food crops, fruit, and livestock. Guyana
produces rice, an important staple and source of income for small
farmers. CARICOM countries export some of
the output of their agricultural sub-sector, as in the case of
Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago, which export various agricultural
commodities and agro-industrial products to countries within and
without the region. However, much of the production in this
sub-sector is for subsistence and domestic markets.
The manufacturing sector differs from country to country in its
size and in its composition. In Barbados it is a vestige of its
former self when the country was home to a large number of foreign
manufacturing firms that produced for the extra-regional market.
Today most of the manufacturing firms in Barbados produce for local
and regional markets. Although it produces a variety of manufactured
products, Guyana has never had a large manufacturing sector--the
contribution of manufacturing to the GDP of that country in 1997 was
about 3.1 percent (table 1). Jamaica and Trinidad and Tobago have a
more diverse manufacturing sector than Barbados and Guyana. Trinidad
and Tobago manufactures steel and, like Jamaica, produces some
chemicals.
The mining sector in CARICOM,
consisting primarily of petroleum, bauxite, and natural gas, makes
an important contribution to the GDP of some countries. In Barbados
it consists mainly of petroleum. The sector's contribution to the
GDP of Barbados in 1997 was about 0.5 percent (table 1). Petroleum
output is usually less than domestic demand. Between 1978 and 1997
domestic crude oil production exceeded 50 percent of domestic needs
only twice (Barbados Ministry of Finance and Economic Affairs 1999,
A32). According to Larry Rother (1998, C1), Trinidad and Tobago
produces about 130,000 barrels of petroleum a day and has proven
natural gas reserves of about 21 trillion cubic feet. The mining
sector in Trinidad and Tobago has played an important role in the
country's growth and development. Petroleum alone contributed about
28.3 percent to GDP in 1997 (table 1). Mining in Guyana contributed
about 14.6 percent to GDP in 1997 (table 1). Both Guyana and Jamaica
have large quantities of bauxite. Guyana also produces gol d and
diamonds of which reserves are yet undetermined but believed to be
significant. Most of the mining output is exported to the more
developed countries.
Export tourism is the biggest industry in the Caribbean. It is
the principal generator of employment and growth in many countries,
and it is also an important earner of foreign exchange. The
Caribbean Tourism Organization (CTO) reported that the Caribbean
tourism industry employed about 578,000 persons in 1995 and tourist
expenditures were about US$12,683 billion (CTO 1995). In Barbados
tourism has long surpassed sugar as the leading industry, and its
contribution to GDP is not insignificant. (7) Tourism expenditure in
Jamaica was about 23.5 percent of GDP in 1995 (table 1). Like other
major CARICOM export commodities and
products, CARICOM tourism exports go
mainly to the more developed countries. The tourist industry in
Guyana and Trinidad and Tobago is not so developed as it is in
Barbados and Jamaica, and it thus plays a smaller role in the growth
of these two economies. Tourism expenditure in Guyana was about 9.2
percent of GDP in 1995, and in Trinidad and Tobago it was about 1.7
percent in 1994 (table 1 ).
The preceding paragraphs described the production structure of
CARICOM countries, which has not changed
fundamentally since colonial times. The production structure has had
a retarding effect on the structural transformation of CARICOM economies. Resources are geared
primarily to export production; the level of food production is low;
backward and forward linkages are minimal; and the foreign investor
still plays an important role in the production of goods and
services in many countries. I shall now try to explain why Barbados
had a better economic performance than the other three countries.
Government Intervention and the Market
In order to meet the aspirations of their peoples that had not
too long ago attained political independence--all four countries
gained their political independence from Britain in the 1960s--CARICOM governments enacted policies in the
early 1970s to remove the path dependence that resulted from more
than 300 years of colonial rule and that blocked economic
development. One manifestation of the path dependence that blocked
economic development was the relative absence of national ownership
of national resources. Economists such as Norman Girvan (1971),
George Beckford (1972), and those working at the Commonwealth
Caribbean Regional Secretariat (1972) were some of the leading
proponents of this view. The Commonwealth Caribbean Regional
Secretariat said,
[T]oo much control of the economies has been exercised from
abroad... particularly by the international corporations in the form
of direct foreign investment. Too much reliance for economic
expansion has been placed on foreign private investment ... the
historical prime mover in the economies in the Region. Thus ... at
least up to the last three years... large parts of the economies of
the Region have been dominated by foreign investment: Sugar (except
in Barbados); Minerals (Oil and bauxite); a large part of the
manufacturing sector; a large part of the tourist sector; the
banking and financial system; and in some cases even the mass media.
In many of the smaller countries, large areas of land have been
alienated on a freehold basis to foreigners in connection with
tourist, real estate and residential development. (1972, 13)
It was argued that foreign ownership of CARICOM resources meant that national resources
were used not for the promotion of national development but for the
development of those countries whose nationals controlled CARICOM resources. Raw materials such as
bauxite and petroleum were not used to manufacture products within
the region but were exported unprocessed. Thus secondary and
tertiary incomes were lost to local economies and minimal backward
and forward linkages were generated. There was a continual outflow
of profits that, had they been invested within local economies,
would have helped to alleviate poverty and promote development. The
implication of these arguments was that foreign ownership of
national resources contributed to underdevelopment in the region and
that a prerequisite for development was that national resources
should be nationally owned.
Persuaded by such arguments, and in an effort to mollify
nationalist sentiment, the governments of Guyana, Jamaica, and
Trinidad and Tobago adopted development strategies in the 1970s that
reduced the role of the private sector and dramatically increased
that of government in the provisioning of goods and services. Guyana
became a socialist co-operative Republic in 1970, and the government
of Jamaica led by Michael Manley--1972-1980--adopted democratic
socialism. Both governments sought greater control of "the
commanding heights" of the economy because, as Manley said,
"political independence and foreign economic domination of strategic
sectors of the economy are mutually exclusive concepts" (1974, 104).
The "commanding heights" of the economy were considered communal
property--the presence of common property resources provides a
justification for government intervention--and nationalizations were
necessary to prevent tragedies of the commons. His government took
over the public utilities; about half of the major hotels;
foreign-owned sugar estates; Barclay's Bank, a British multinational
bank; and the cement factory. It set up the Jamaica State Trading
Corporation, which was responsible for the importation of all goods
crucial to the country's development, and it purchased 50 percent of
the bauxite mining operations and land (Manley 1982).
The government of Guyana took control not only of sugarcane
production and bauxite-alumina production but also of "retail
distribution outlets, drug manufacture, alcohol production,
shipping, cable and wireless communications, foundries and
small-scale ship yards...." (Thomas 1983, 30). Furthermore, it
established several companies under the control of the Guyana State
Corporation (GUYSTAC). Its External Trade Bureau controlled all
imports and exports. By 1976 the government of Guyana controlled 80
percent of the economy.
The government of Trinidad and Tobago, too, increased the role of
the state relative to that of the private sector in the provisioning
of goods and services. It entered into joint partnerships with
foreign multinational companies, and by the early 1980s it had built
at Point Lisas an iron and steel plant, two ammonia plants, a urea
plant, and a methanol plant and it owned some sixty-seven companies.
The governments of these three countries reversed their policies
in the l980s. Edward Seaga became prime minister of Jamaica in
October 1980 and soon began to sell off state-owned enterprises
(SOEs) and liberalize Jamaica's trade regime (Ambursley 1983, 96).
Seaga said, "We have to structurally adjust the direction of the
economy, so that instead of continuing to be protected by various
devices such as quantitative restrictions and other barriers, it
will be mobilized for the external market" (Francis-Hinds 1982, 6).
(8) Likewise, when he became president of Guyana upon the death of
Forbes Burnham in 1985, Desmond Hoyte began to adopt a more
market-oriented approach to development. According to Caribbean
Contact (1989, 6), "Hoyte ... took the initiative and began to
dismantle the rigidities of the state stranglehold by divesting
those government-owned companies that produced negative returns."
Prime Minister A. N. R. Robinson said in 1987 that his government
had no alternative but to restructure some of the sixty-seven
state-owned enterprises that were losing large sums of money or shut
them down (Mackoon, 1987a, 2).
Although the governments of Guyana, Jamaica, and Trinidad and
Tobago adopted free market policies, economic conditions in their
countries did not materially improve. Table 2 shows that Guyana's
real annual average growth of gross national product (GNP) per
capita was zero during 1970-79 and shrank during the period 1980-90
but that it improved significantly between 1990 and 1997-12.9
percent. (9) Jamaica's real average annual growth of GNP per capita
shrank during 1970-79 and 1980-90 and grew less than 1 percent
during 1990-97. Trinidad and Tobago had a real average annual growth
of GNP per capita of 4.5 percent during the period 1970-1979, owing
in great measure to the steep oil prices of that decade. However,
falling oil prices during the 1980s adversely affected the country's
economic performance. The real average growth of GNP per capita
shrank 6.0 percent during the period 1980-90 and 1.4 percent during
1990-97.
Compared with the governments of the other CARICOM countries, the government of Barbados
did not significantly expand its role in the provisioning of
non-public goods. Barbados does not possess traditional natural
resources, and Barbadians have for a very long time owned the
country's agricultural resources. Consequently, an
anti-foreign-investment sentiment that might have forced the
government to acquire foreign assets that it did not have the
technical and human resources to manage never really took hold in
the country. Also, unable to rely on the export of traditional
natural resources, Barbadian governments sought to develop new
exports like tourism. In addition, the country attracted foreign
direct investment, partly because of its stable political and social
environment. Many international firms such as Intel set up
operations in Barbados and helped the economy to grow. Between
1970-79 and 1980-90, the country's real annual average growth rate
of GNP per capita increased by 2.1 and 1.4 percent respect ively;
but between 1990 and 1997, it shrank by 0.9 percent (table 2). (10)
Between 1972 and 1997 the real GNP per capita of Barbados increased
eightfold from US$800 to US$6,590; and by 1997 it was eight times
greater than that of Guyana, four times greater than that of
Jamaica, and one and a half times greater than that of Trinidad and
Tobago (figure 1). As table 3 shows, other indicators of development
were generally just as, or more, favorable in Barbados than in the
other three countries.
An institutionalist approach to development can help explain why
some CARICOM countries did not have the
economic performance that some had expected. Institutional change is
central to economic growth, but institutions are interrelated and as
one changes so must the others. However, some institutions are very
slow to change or may not change and they thus slow down the process
of economic and social transformation. The rules surrounding the
provisioning of goods and services underwent radical change in some
CARICOM countries, but the rules of the
supportive institutions that were necessary to make the policy
successful hardly changed.
If foreign investors must be replaced because they are
responsible for underdevelopment, there must be a national
manufacturing entrepreneurial class to take their place. CARICOM governments implicitly assumed the
existence of a national manufacturing class or, if they did not,
thought that such a class would quickly emerge to exploit the new
opportunities created by nationalization and import-substitution
industrialization. But the colonial system discouraged the
development of manufacturing because it was competitive with
metropolitan manufacturing. Eric Williams (1970, 173) said, "The
colonial system placed particular emphasis on the prohibition of
colonial manufactures." Likewise, D. K. Fieldhouse (1981, 68) stated
that colonial "industrial production was virtually ignored... [and]
that the duty of government was to keep the peace, and not to
stimulate [colonial] industrial development or indigenous
enterprise." The attempt to keep colonial industrial production to a
minimum meant that the indigenous manufacturing class in former
colonies would be underdeveloped.
.gif) Ayres said "the most important factor in the economic life
of any people is the educational level... of the community." The
educational level he had in mind was one that produced "a
technically sophisticated community" because such a community "can
and will equip itself with the instrumentalities of an industrial
economy" (1962, xxi). CARICOM educational
systems were not designed to promote the kind of society Ayres had
in mind. Sir Arthur Lewis' earlier observation of educational
systems in less developed countries is true of CARICOM today. He said,
Because the pattern of education was formed many centuries before
the modern technological revolution occurred, most education systems
give too little weight to the natural sciences and technology,
whether at primary, secondary or higher levels so that a surfeit of
persons trained in literary studies side by side with an acute
shortage of persons trained in scientific, biological or mechanical
arts, is a feature of several countries. (1961, 114)
The lack of emphasis in the school curricula on subjects that can
help to promote the growth of an indigenous manufacturing class is a
direct consequence of the colonial experience. Fieldhouse (1982, 69)
said, "Colonial officials seldom came from industrial or commercial
backgrounds and tended to despise these activities as
ungentlemanly." They designed the colonial educational systems, and
they made sure that they were consistent with the dominant values in
metropolitan countries. Most former colonial subjects, especially
those that have received a secondary or tertiary education, have
internalized these negative values toward industrial production.
Thus, if given the opportunity to take silk or become an industrial
entrepreneur, few CARICOM students will
pursue the latter. Such ceremonialism helps to stifle the growth of
an indigenous manufacturing class.
Another element stifling the growth of an indigenous
manufacturing class has been the banking system. Many commercial
banks are subsidiaries of metropolitan multinational corporations,
and they cater primarily to the import-export trade. They are also
reluctant to lend to non-European manufacturers that wish to
undertake manufacturing production. Commercial banks in CARICOM show a strong preference for
self-liquidating loans, and they direct most of their loans to the
distributive trades category and the personal loan category-mainly
for the purchase of consumer goods. The bias in commercial bank
lending toward the distributive trades and personal loans was a
feature of colonial banking, but it continues in the post-colonial
period although many commercial banks have been nationalized or
localized. Undoubtedly these sectors help economies to grow, but
they contribute little to structural transformation. The merchant
classes do not revolutionize the means of production because they
can make a profit irrespecti ve of the mode of production. They are
usually opposed to the development of manufacturing because they
consider its development a threat to their economic and political
power.
.gif) As a
result of the absence of a significant national entrepreneurial
class, the domestic output of many goods that were to be produced by
indigenous manufacturers under a program of import substitution
never reached levels to satisfy domestic demand. Commenting on the
import-substitution strategy by the government of Guyana, the Latin
American Bureau (1984, 51) wrote, "An ever-increasing range of goods
became short in supply, with the long-term effect of an overall drop
in consumption levels. Ventures such as fruit canning factories,
cassava mills, a corn and soya company and saltfish production all
came into existence, but never flourished, and by 1978 had all but
gone out of business." Manley (1987, 83) wrote, "In spite of
tremendous efforts [in Jamaical to reduce the dependence on imports
between 1972 and 1980, there was actually an increase of 4 percent
over the period."
The relative absence of an entrepreneurial class adversely
affected not only import-substitution industrialization but also
nationalized bauxite industries as few nationals had the expertise
to manage them. Between 1970 and 1979 bauxite production in Guyana
declined from 3,082 million tonnes to 1,626 million tones, and
alumina production declined during the same period from 312,000
tonnes to 160,000 tonnes (Central Bank of Barbados 1996, 222). In
Jamaica, the nationalization of bauxite and the levy that went into
effect May 15, 1974, contributed to a decline in bauxite production.
(11) Bauxite production, which was about 15.3 million tonnes in
1974, fell to about 12 million tonnes in 1980; and alumina
production, which was about 2.8 million tonnes in 1974, fell to 2.4
million tonnes in 1980 (cited in Manley 1987, 61). Another element
contributing to production declines was that bauxite companies,
which engage in much intra-firm trade, were able to increase bauxite
production in other countries such as Guinea , whose taxes on
bauxite exports were about 50 percent lower than the levies imposed
by Caribbean countries (Manley 1980, 80) (12) The policies of CARICOM governments, which induced bauxite
companies to change their production strategies, contributed to
declines in bauxite production. Nevertheless, it cannot be denied
that a lack of technology and entrepreneurship also played a part.
And since bauxite was a prime mover of the economies of Guyana and
Jamaica, declines in production adversely affected their economic
growth.
Production in the other major export industries of Guyana and
Jamaica also declined, although the declines cannot be completely
attributed to a lack of entrepreneurial skills. Sugar output fell in
both countries. Rice production in Guyana fluctuated because of low
prices set by the government, shortages of inputs, a neglected
infrastructure, and a ban on rice exports to Cuba (Baber and Jeffrey
1986, 147; Latin American Bureau 1984, 47). Tourism exports from
Jamaica declined because of social unrest--the government was forced
to declare a state of emergency in 1976 because of the extreme
deterioration of the social and political climate--and the ensuing
negative coverage the country received in the financial press of its
main tourism-export markets. The year after the government declared
a state of emergency, tourist arrivals in Jamaica fell by 67,000;
and in 1980, the year of national elections, they fell by 30,000
(Central Bank of Barbados 1996, 215).
The decline in the output of the leading export industries
resulted in a loss of foreign exchange earnings. In addition, some
countries experienced capital flight. Michael Kaufman (1985, 123)
said that about US$200 million illegally left Jamaica between 1975
and 1976. The loss of foreign-exchange earnings and heavy capital
outflows reduced the country's ability to import the many inputs
needed for production, further contributing to falling output. The
manufacturing sector, which depended heavily on a variety of
imported inputs, was adversely affected, and manufacturing exports
from Jamaica fell during the second half of the 1970s.
Trinidad and Tobago enjoyed a favorable external marker for its
principal export during the 1970s. An oil-producing country,
Trinidad and Tobago benefited from the steep rise in oil prices of
that decade. During the period 1974-83, the government of Trinidad
and Tobago received about US$10 billion in oil revenues (Farrell
1986, 8). As I have mentioned, the state entered into joint
partnerships with some foreign multinational companies and
established an iron and steel complex at Point Lisas, which was to
be the catalyst for industrial development by using local
hydrocarbon resources. The then prime minister, Dr. Eric Williams,
justified the construction of the iron and steel complex on the
grounds that "the production of steel, possibly of all man-made
products, has been for many years and will continue in the future to
be a bench mark for industrial development and any form of serious
industrialization." (1981, 83).
During the decade of the 1980s, however, with the demand for oil
falling and its oil revenues drying up, the economy of Trinidad and
Tobago, like those of Guyana and Jamaica, contracted. Real GNP per
capita, which in 1982 was US$6,920, fell to US$3,400 in 1989.
Moreover, the SOEs did not turn out to be the force for development
that many had expected. The SOEs were asking for financial
assistance to the amount of $2.7 billion in 1987 (Mackoon 1987a, 2),
the Iron and Steel Company (ISCOTT) was reported to be losing US$5
million a day, and the state-owned Caroni Ltd, the country's only
sugar factory, was said to be a drain on the Treasury (Mackoon,
1987b, 2). Like Guyana and Jamaica, Trinidad and Tobago experienced
foreign exchange difficulties with severe economic and social
consequences. Mackoon (1989, 5) wrote that "[h]arsh foreign exchange
problems have led to shortages like cheese and powdered milk.
Businesses have been hit hard by cuts in foreign exchange
allocations and some have had to close because of a shortage of raw
materials."
CARICOM countries encouraged
import-substitution industrialization to help transform their
economies. A successful import-industrialization program will result
in higher levels of employment, the creation of forward and backward
linkages within local economies, the saving of scarce foreign
exchange, and the promotion of growth and development. An important
ingredient in the success of the program is to get consumers to
switch from foreign products to domestic substitutes. CARICOM countries, however, suffer from a
debilitating path dependence in consumption patterns that have
contributed to the slow economic transformation in Caribbean
countries (Commonwealth Caribbean Regional Secretariat 1972, 21).
For example, the government of Guyana wanted to replace imported
wheaten flour with domestic rice flour, but the policy met with
strong opposition. Colin Baber and Henry Jeffrey (1986, 137) labeled
the policy absurd because "from time immemorial [wheaten flour] has
been an intrinsic part of the daily diet of the vast majority of the
people and they resent the Government's restriction. The authors
were obviously using the phrase "from time immemorial" to mean from
the time the institution of colonialism was imposed on Guyana
because, before colonization, the indigenous people of that country
did not import wheaten flour. (13) The authors ignored a very
important fact in the development of a country: a country using
domestic resources to produce goods for domestic consumption will
enjoy a higher level of growth and development than if it imports
substitutes for consumption. In addition, if other Caribbean
governments had been able to get their citizens to consume rice
flour instead of wheaten flour, the rice industry in Guyana and
related industries might have received a significant boost, thus
helping that country's development and strengthening regional
economic integration. The authors, however, seemed to be suggesting
that, in trying to effect economic and social transformation,
governments should make no effort to change ceremonial patterns of
consumption. This is a clear instance where the forces of
ceremonialism were much stronger than the forces promoting economic
and social transformation.
CARICOM governments that tried to
transform their economies by nationalizing foreign assets or by
promoting import-substitution industrialization underestimated the
negative impact of path dependence and ceremonialism on the
development of an indigenous entrepreneurial class, which is
indispensable to transformation. They changed the rules of
production, but the rules of supportive institutions remained
virtually unchanged and thus the level of economic development
declined. Unable to undermine ceremonialism and eliminate the
debilitating path dependence inherited from colonial rule, some
CARICOM governments were not successful
in using market or directed policies to move their economies to
higher levels of development.
Natural Resources
According to the staple theory of growth, a country discovering a
primary commodity in which it has a comparative advantage, and which
it exports, will realize high rates of economic growth and per
capita income, lower underemployment and unemployment, higher rates
of saving and investment, and greater backward and forward linkages
(Meier 1984, 491). Skeptics, however, are not so sure that countries
with natural resources will always reap such benefits (Ranis 1981;
Passell 1995, D2; McShane 1995, 40; Phillips 2000, A1), partly
because institutional elements may block change.
Gustav Ranis (1981) argued that the relative abundance of natural
resources in Latin America allowed countries of that region to
continue to rely on the exportation of traditional raw materials and
pursue inefficient import-substitution industrialization behind high
tariff walls. The exportation of traditional raw materials benefited
the politically powerful agricultural classes, and inefficient
import-substitution industrialization benefited urban workers and
entrepreneurs. Those benefiting from the existing production
structure opposed changes to the system and permitted "the system to
continue on its old tracks, thus avoiding the political and, at
least short-term, economic pain of having to move to a different
policy package" (180). Ranis, therefore, implied that a relative
abundance of natural resources, given certain institutional
features, can block the structural transformation of some economies.
Natural resources can also be detrimental to some countries
because of the "Dutch Disease"(14)--Ranis (1981, 180) used the term
"Kuwait Effect" to describe a similar phenomenon that occurred in
Kuwait. As production of the natural resource increases, production
in the traded manufacturing sector tends to decline--a Rybcznski
effect seems to be at work. (15) The increased demand for labor and
capital in the natural-resource sector will cause wages and interest
rates to rise, thus attracting labor and capital from the traded
manufacturing sector. Higher costs of production will cause the
traded manufacturing sector to contract. Moreover, assuming flexible
exchange rates, the national currency will appreciate in
foreign-exchange markets, making exports from the traded
manufacturing sector less competitive.
The "Dutch Disease" cannot explain the poor economic performance
of Jamaica, Guyana, and Trinidad and Tobago relative to that of
Barbados. The data suggest that the output of their natural
resources did not experience any significant expansion (Central Bank
of Barbados 1999, 228). Moreover, the capital-intensive character of
extractive industries does not lead to much employment creation. It
is therefore highly unlikely that the mining sector attracted labor
and capital away from the traded manufacturing sector, or from other
export sectors, thus causing production costs in those sectors to
rise and their exports to become less competitive. Besides, CARICOM resource-endowed countries experienced
high levels of unemployment and, instead of currency appreciation,
as the "Dutch Disease" predicts, their currencies were devalued
steeply.
Less developed countries with natural resources tend to
experience much corruption, with some elected leaders allegedly
siphoning off for themselves and their families vast amounts of
wealth that should be used for improving the economic and social
conditions of the population. Such an allegation was made against
some elected officials in Indonesia, Nigeria, and Zaire, now renamed
Democratic Republic of Congo. These three countries are resource
rich, but their social development is among the lowest of all
countries. (16) Likewise, some of the most virulent allegations of
corruption in CARICOM were made against
the governments of countries blessed with natural resources. Larry
Rother (1998, C1) alleged that during the oil bonanza in Trinidad
and Tobago billions of oil profits were squandered or pilfered. On
the other hand, Barbados, with few known natural resources,
distinguished itself among CARICOM
nations "in providing good government free of the corruption [found]
elsewhere in the region" (Singh 1987, 6). Rickey Singh obviously did
not mean to suggest that no corruption existed among elected
officials in Barbados but that the level of corruption in Barbados
was negligible compared with its CARICOM
neighbors.
Less developed countries that are endowed with natural resources
may not be blessed for another very important reason--the character
of production processes is changing dramatically. In the new
industrial order, natural resources are not so important an element
in the production process as, for example, in the heyday of
pre-World War II industrialization. The United Nations (1990,
150-5), noting the developments occurring in the new materials
technology, said that new materials "will reduce the growth of
demand for such traditional materials as copper, zinc, tin, bauxite
and aluminium." Competitive pressures, also, are forcing scientists
to turn away "from mechanical systems requiring heavy metals,
combustion, and petroleum to seek solutions that use minimal inputs,
lower temperatures, and enzymatic reactions" (Hawken et al. 1999,
15). Moreover, some governments in the more developed countries, the
principal markets for traditional natural resources from less
developed countries, have committed to pursuing F actor Four (a 75
percent reduction in energy and materials intensity) and Factor Ten
(a 90 percent reduction) efficiencies (11-12).
Human investment skills have displaced natural resources as the
main inputs in many production processes, and countries that have an
abundance of human investment skills will be more prosperous than
countries that have scanty human investment skills. Singapore,
excluding its geographical location, has no natural resources, but
it is abundant in human skills that it uses to continually transform
its economy. This may be one reason that its real GNP per capita is
higher than those of many countries that are well endowed with
natural resources.
Evolutionary Economic Change
To focus solely on developments in the new materials technology,
human investment skills, and changing business practices in the more
developed countries may not completely explain why CARICOM countries with natural resources did
not perform very well economically over the last two decades or so.
Owing partly to a shortage of technical and manufacturing
entrepreneurial skills and partly to the commercial policies of the
more developed countries, which tend to be biased against
manufactures from less developed countries with a high
natural-resource content, CARICOM
countries have never developed any significant manufacturing
industries through indigenous effort based on their natural
resources. Consequently, they have tended to depend more on
exporting their natural resources than on exporting manufactured
products derived from their natural resources. In the process a
psychology has developed that downturns in natural-resource exports
resulting from external elements are temporary and that conditions
will so on return to their former equilibrium. It becomes difficult
to appreciate the fact that capitalism is an evolutionary system and
that a new environment is emerging in which some traditional natural
resources will play a diminished role in production processes or in
fact will be completely replaced. The failure to understand the
evolutionary character of capitalism to which CARICOM industries must continually adapt has
helped to contribute to a lack of institutional dynamism. And the
lack of institutional dynamism, in addition to other things, has
slowed the process of structural transformation in CARICOM.
Ranis' explanation of why resource-rich Latin American countries
have performed poorly compared with resource-poor East Asian
countries may help to explain why Barbados had a better economic
performance than other CARICOM countries.
Having no traditional natural resources such as bauxite and oil
reserves on which to rely for economic growth, Barbados exploited
some of the changes occurring in the global environment that
permitted it to use its natural resources to good advantage.
Successive governments realized that the global market for
international tourism was becoming favorable. The advent of jet
travel, rising incomes in the more developed countries, the
wide-bodied jet that carried a large number of passengers and
allowed airlines to realize economies of scale and reduce airfares,
the closure of the Cuban tourist plant during the Cold War, and the
emergence of tour operators all helped tourism exports from the
English-speaking CARICOM to grow.
Governments were also acutely aware that, unlike commodity exports,
rent-seekers in tourism-importing countries do not emerge demanding
protection from tourism imports and that very few countries impose
travel bans on their citizens. Consequently, they allocated more and
more resources to the development of the tourist industry.
Tourism in Barbados was initially a luxury export, undertaken
principally by foreign-owned luxury hotels. But as the average
tourist became less wealthy, the Barbadian tourist plant changed to
accommodate less affluent tourists without neglecting the more
affluent ones. Thus by the late 1980s, small and medium-sized hotels
provided some 80 percent of the hotel beds in Barbados, and, because
they were owned mainly by Barbadians, they had the greatest
potential for retention of earnings and creation of local employment
(Government of Barbados 1988, 99). Barbadians benefited in other
ways from tourism expansion. For example, most of the taxis and
hired cars in Barbados cater to tourists and so do the traditional
handicraft industries. In addition, domestic agriculture, which is
dominated by small producers, has benefited as tourists have shown a
strong preference for local foods. And as governments ensured that
Barbadians had access to the same amenities as the tourists--for
example, all beaches in Barbados are open to the public--minimal
conflict between tourists and nationals ensued. The relatively good
relationship between tourists and locals, a stable social and
political climate, and a reputation as a country not hostile to
visitors have helped to create an environment favorable to tourism
expansion and have enabled Barbados to have a high percentage of
repeat visitors. (17)
Some CARICOM governments did not take
advantage of the changes in the international environment that
favored the expansion of regional tourism. For example, the
government of Trinidad and Tobago did not encourage export tourism.
When he was head of the Economic Planning Division of the government
of Trinidad and Tobago, William Demas (1965, 59-60) wrote: "It is
true that tourism is highly income-elastic, but it depends so
largely on whim and fashion that it would not be prudent in
countries where it is possible to develop manufactures to place hope
entirely or largely on this industry." He argued that tourism did
not have the capacity to transform economies, although it might be
appropriate for countries that had the natural advantages for
tourism but little potential for manufacturing. (18) Guyana has
never been attractive to "sun-lust" tourists. Nor did the government
of Guyana, despite that country's natural advantages, try to promote
eco-tourism, partly because of a relatively underdeveloped
infrastructu re. Jamaica benefited from the expansion of regional
tourism; but the continuing unfavorable reporting in the financial
press of that country's main tourism export markets (Jamaica
Gleaner, April 23, 2001) has prevented its tourist industry from
reaching its full economic potential.
It may be instructive to contrast the economic responses of the
governments of Barbados and Trinidad and Tobago to an evolving
global environment. The government of Trinidad and Tobago, hamstrung
by a pre--World War II view of the role of traditional resources in
the process of economic development, could not free itself from the
belief that heavy industry based on steel would continue to play the
role it played in early industrialization. On the other hand, the
government of Barbados encouraged the development of the tourist
industry, an industry with high income elasticities of demand and
high growth prospects. (19) They did not cling to the view of
foreign advisers that it was difficult to create employment off the
land (Hagelberg 1985, 29), that is, outside the sugar industry.
Indeed, they could not rely on the sugar industry to earn increasing
amounts of foreign exchange as cane sugar was facing an uncertain
future because of intense competition from artificial sweeteners,
high fructose corn syrup, and beet sugar, and because of trade
restrictions in some markets of the more developed countries, As I
have mentioned, sugar had ceased to be the leading generator of
income. Barbadian governments exploited the country's natural
advantages in tourism and maintained a stable political and social
environment, which is necessary for the growth of tourism exports.
Caribbean export tourism has been the subject of much criticism,
much of it focusing on the social costs that have accompanied its
growth (Kempadoo 1999). (20) But by the mid 1980s Barbados tourism
exports had become the country's leading foreign exchange earner and
a significant employer of labor. (21) Barbados' better economic
performance was partly due to an absence of traditional raw
materials, which forced its governments to allocate increasing
amounts of resources to the promotion of export tourism in order to
earn foreign exchange and create additional jobs.
Trade Unions
Trade unions have played an important role in the economic,
political, and social development of CARICOM countries. They have been able to get
governments to pass legislation that resulted in better working
conditions, a shorter workweek, maternity leave, minimum wages, paid
vacations, paid sick leave, and severance pay, partly because of
their long association with the leading political parties, which
have traditionally depended on them for electoral and financial
support. (22) Many of their leaders have sat in parliament, and some
of them have held the highest elected office in their country.
In order to achieve their objectives, trade unions in CARICOM have frequently resorted to strikes.
Baber and Jeffrey (1986, 112) said 653 strikes took place in Guyana
in 1982. Work stoppages in the mining sector of Jamaica rose from
nine in 1974 to sixty-one in 1975 but fell to twenty-four in 1976
(cited in Kaufman 1985, 106). Table 4 shows that during the period
1985-95 Guyana had the most strikes and lockouts, followed by
Trinidad and Tobago and Barbados. And table 5 shows Guyana had the
most workdays not worked and Barbados had the fewest. Since Barbados
had the fewest strikes and lockouts, and the fewest workdays not
worked, it might be reasonable to suggest that the loss of output in
Barbados from industrial unrest was lower than in the other
countries that had more strikes and more workdays not worked. The
data may also suggest that Barbados had a healthier industrial
climate than the other countries and this may help to explain the
country's better economic performance.
It is difficult to estimate the cost of industrial unrest to
CARICOM economies. The cost must be
measured not only in terms of lost output but also, in addition to
other elements, in terms of lost potential investment, local and
foreign. It cannot be known how much potential direct foreign
investment was lost to the region because of industrial unrest.
Nevertheless, it is safe to assume that industrial unrest may have
dissuaded some investors from setting up plants in the region and
induced others in the region to relocate. The potential and actual
loss of investment would have helped contribute to slower economic
growth.
Some of the industrial unrest that took place in CARICOM was due to workers protesting the
deteriorating economic and social conditions arising from government
policies. Governments reduced or eliminated subsidies on traditional
basic foodstuffs and in some instances, as happened in Barbados, cut
public sector wages. Shortages of certain basic food items, to which
the populations were accustomed, led to price increases. Fitzroy
Ambursley (1983, 85) said that after eight years of democratic
socialism in Jamaica the cost of living had increased by 320
percent. The urban consumer price index in Guyana rose from 100 in
1970 to 196.5 in 1978 to 448.5 in 1983 (Faber and Jeffrey 1986,
115). Free-market policies did not have better results. Table 6
shows that the consumer price index in Jamaica rose from 100 in 1990
to 669.5 in 1996. Consequently, real wages fell and standards of
living declined. In the deteriorating economic and social
environment, workers went out on strike to bring to the attention of
elected off icials their dissatisfaction with their lot.
Some members of the old institutionalist school (Veblen 1899) and
the new institutionalist school (Olson 1982) sometimes assert that
institutions may serve only their particular interests and by so
doing work against the general good of society. Ranis' account of
the role of the powerful agricultural classes, urban workers, and
entrepreneurs in Latin American countries in resisting changes to
the structure of production tends to support this assertion. The
Commonwealth Caribbean Regional Secretariat (1972, 25), too, seemed
to share this view, describing the institution of the Caribbean
trade union as dysfunctional and a metropolitan import that is
irrelevant to the realities of the peculiar CARICOM situation. But institutions sometimes
modify their behavior in response to a changing environment, and
they are also capable of sacrificing their particular interests for
the good of the community.
.gif) As
the global economy became more integrated during the 1980s, the
number of global manufacturing competitors increased and so did the
level of global price competition. Multinational corporations were
forced to look for production locations that enabled them to reduce
production costs. They sought out locations that offered, in
addition to other things, inputs of production at competitive
prices. They found many Asian countries particularly attractive
because, not only were wages lower than in CARICOM, but also trade union activity was
severely curtailed in many Asian states, thus giving capital greater
leverage over labor. Trade union leaders in Barbados realized the
disadvantage in which Barbados found itself and they therefore
adopted a new approach to industrial relations to help prevent the
closure of foreign manufacturing plants in Barbados. They began to
work with firms to increase worker productivity in order to restore
and maintain the competitiveness of Barbadian products and services.
Robert Morri s, the Deputy General Secretary of the Barbados
Workers' Union, echoed the new attitude of trade unions when he
said, "The union and the workforce have a deep responsibility to
encourage productivity at the workplace if our goods and services
are to be competitive in the marketplace" (Barbados Nation, March
15, 2001). Morris recognized that foreign manufacturing production
in Barbados is very mobile, that it is not committed to any
particular geographical unit, that it will move to locations where
labor is available at competitive prices, and that therefore
Barbadian labor will have to adjust to meet the needs of foreign
capital.
Another change in the attitude of the trade union movement in
Barbados occurred when the economy of Barbados experienced a deep
recession from 1990-1992. Export earnings declined, foreign exchange
reserves fell dramatically, the generous income tax allowances of
earlier years resulted in huge fiscal deficits, and GDP fell an
average of 4 percent annually. The government of Barbados responded
to the economic crisis by introducing an economic stabilization
program that included an incomes policy. The incomes policy sought,
in addition to other things, "to restrain the rate of wage increases
in order to keep prices down...[and] put in place a more appropriate
process for wage settlements based on linkages to and changes in
productivity" (Sandiford 1993, 10). Recognizing that the deep
recession the country was experiencing required drastic measures,
trade unions supported the government austerity program because they
believed that a currency devaluation, as the IMF wanted the
government to engage in, would have b rought similar undesirable
economic and social consequences to Barbados as it had done to other
CARICOM countries that had devalued their
currencies. They joined employers and the government and signed a
protocol in 1993 affirming their commitment to work together for the
economic good of the country. They have since signed additional
protocols; the most recent took place May Day 2000. (23) Senator
LeRoy Trotman, general secretary of the Barbados Workers' Union and
head of the Congress of Trade Unions and Staff Associations of
Barbados, said that no other single act of governance has done more
to facilitate the "mutual upliftment of the country" than the
protocol and partnership arrangement (Barbados Nation, May 2, 2000).
.gif) Exchange-Rate Policy
With the exception of Trinidad and Tobago during the oil crisis
of the 1970s, CARICOM countries have had
low foreign reserve balances for a long time. Foreign reserves
balances have sometimes been so critically low that countries have
been forced to seek financial assistance from the IMF. Financial
assistance from the IMF is usually given to countries on the
condition that, in addition to adopting other policies, they devalue
their currencies. Devaluation should make the country's exports more
competitive and reduce imports. Net exports will therefore rise and
so will the foreign reserves of the central bank. Domestic
employment, also, will rise as domestic production rises to satisfy
the increased domestic and foreign demand for the country's products
and services.
.gif) A
successful devaluation, however, depends on some strong assumptions.
The elasticities of demand and supply must be high; the economy must
be at less than full employment; countries must not retaliate in
response to the devaluation; and free trade must prevail. If these
assumptions hold, devaluation will be successful; if they do not,
devaluation may be baneful medicine, especially for small countries
such as those of CARICOM.
CARICOM countries do not produce many
products that can benefit from a devaluation. (24) The principal
agricultural exports go mainly to the markets of the more developed
countries. In theory, devaluation should cause the volume of exports
to increase as goods become less expensive in terms of foreign
currencies. But the principal CARICOM
agricultural exports face formidable trade barriers in the more
developed countries. Sugar and bananas are subject to quotas. The
more significant manufactures are also subject to restricted trade
in the markets of the more developed countries. Thus devaluation is
of little help in causing the volume of the principal CARICOM export products to increase.
In addition to barriers to trade, supply elasticities in CARICOM are low. This is evident in the
production of sugar where, as I have mentioned, some countries have
had great difficulty meeting their quotas for sugar in EU markets.
Low supply elasticities in the production of bauxite were also
evident during the late 1970s. As Manley noted (1987, 77),
"Following the massive devaluation upon which the IMF insisted,
there was virtually no response in terms of bauxite
exports-11,434,000 tonnes in 1977; 11,736,000 tonnes in 1978; 11,
505,000 tonnes in 1979; and 11,991,000 tonnes in 1980." Even apparel
production, which has expanded rapidly in a country like Jamaica,
has low supply elasticities. Foreign producers in that country
undertake most of the apparel production for export and, should they
relocate their plants to other locations, an insufficient number of
local manufacturing entrepreneurs would mean a sudden and dramatic
reduction in apparel output. CARICOM
countries lack a basic ingredient to make devalua tion
successful--they simply do not have the productive capacity to
exploit the opportunities created by devaluation.
Without the productive capacity to exploit the opportunities
created by devaluation, CARICOM countries
will experience little expenditure switching and thus will not
realize any significant reduction in the volume of imports. The
prices of goods that are crucial to the development and daily
functioning of economies will rise in terms of local currency
because of the devaluation and lead to a higher rate of inflation.
Devaluation will not reduce imports for another fundamental reason:
consumption patterns in CARICOM imitate
those of the more developed countries. CARICOM consumers have a strong preference for
foreign goods and services from North America and Western Europe.
This is due in part to "advertising as well as the images of
affluence projected daily and nightly by the mass media (especially
commercial television) as well as the influence of consumption
patterns of tourists from affluent countries visiting the Region"
(Caribbean Commonwealth Regional Secretariat 1972, 21). And since
foreign goods are c onsidered superior to indigenous substitutes,
"the failure to consume [them] in due quantity and quality becomes a
mark of inferiority" (Veblen 1899, 64). If devaluation does not
change the long-run demand and supply conditions, countries that
devalue their currencies will experience inflation to the extent of
the devaluation. Moreover, some investors will most likely believe
that further devaluations will take place and move their funds out
of the country. Thus, devaluation in CARICOM will have the perverse effect of
contributing to an outflow, and not an inflow, of international
reserves.
CARICOM countries that devalued their
currencies, or allowed them to depreciate, had a poorer economic
performance than Barbados, which kept its exchange rate fixed to the
US dollar. For example, the Guyanese dollar has been worth US$0.01
cent for some time, but the low value of the Guyanese dollar in
terms of the US dollar has not resulted in higher levels of Guyanese
exports to the United States as theory would predict. Likewise,
devaluation or depreciation has not resulted in an improvement in
Jamaica's current account balance. The current account balances of
countries that devalued their currencies were no healthier than
those of Barbados, which did not devalue its currency. Barbados
never devalued its currency even when urged to do so by the IMF
during its deep recession of 1990-1992. The government was able to
resist IMF pressure to devalue the Barbadian dollar because all
political parties, trade unions, and "the vast majority of
Barbadians at home and abroad have indicated that they do not want
the pr esent rate parity of Bds. $2.00 to US$1.00 to be changed"
(Sandiford 1993, 10). And despite the government's refusal to
devalue the currency as the IMF had insisted was necessary to cure
the foreign-exchange crisis that arose in the early 1990s, Barbados
realized a surplus in the current account from 1992-6 (United
Nations, 1998). In addition, over the period 1994-1998, Barbados was
the only country whose current account surplus as a percentage of
GDP was positive (Stotsky et al. 2000, 23). The fact that Barbados'
current account was positive during the period 1994-1998 even though
the government did not devalue the currency may suggest that
exchange-rate flexibility is not always the decisive factor in
determining a country's export performance. Furthermore, there seems
to be a direct relationship between devaluation and inflation.
Guyana devalued its currency more than Jamaica; Jamaica devalued its
currency more than Trinidad and Tobago; and Barbados did not devalue
its currency. Inflation was higher in Guy ana than in Jamaica
between 1994 and 1998; both of these countries had higher rates of
inflation than Trinidad and Tobago; and Guyana, Jamaica, and
Trinidad and Tobago all had higher rates of inflation than Barbados.
Conclusion
Societies are continually changing, and therefore institutions
must continually change if they are not to slow down the development
process. But institutions are not independent, and as one changes so
must others. CARICOM governments wish to
transform their economies and they wish national manufacturers to
play a greater role in the process. But transformation will be
difficult to achieve if governments do not place more emphasis in
their educational curricula on subjects that will lead to the
emergence of nationals with an industrial entrepreneurial spirit or
if they are unable to get financial institutions to play a more
supportive role. An educational system that does not disdain
industrial activity and that encourages risk taking will help to
remove the social stigma attached to activities not associated with
the professions. Furthermore, institutions must adapt to changes in
the external environment. Foreign manufacturing firms are extremely
mobile, and they seek out labor wherever they can find it at co
mpetitive prices. CARICOM trade unions
must therefore adapt to the new global reality and become less
confrontational if the region is to be successful in attracting
foreign manufacturing firms. Likewise, traditional products may
experience a secular decline while new products or services are
being demanded. Institutions that were appropriate for the old
environment will not be appropriate for the new environment and slow
down development. Countries whose institutions can adjust to a new
environment will have a much better chance of experiencing a higher
level of development than those whose institutions do not adjust
quickly or fail to adjust.
Notes
(1.) CARICOM is a broad integration
effort among mostly English-speaking Caribbean countries--Haiti and
Suriname have been recently granted membership. The main elements of
CARICOM are economic integration,
functional integration, and co-ordination of foreign policies. The
four countries examined are Barbados, Guyana, Jamaica, and Trinidad
and Tobago, which are usually considered the moat developed in CARICOM.
(2.) See Williams 1970 and Fieldhouse 1981, chapter 2. Fieldhouse
(15) also argues that institutions established in the past can
influence the present level of development.
(3.) All four countries produce sugar. In addition, Jamaica
produces bananas and coffee and Guyana has a large rice sector.
(4.) One Barbadian dollar is worth US$0.50 cents.
(5.) According to Festus Brotherson (1989, 7), Guyana imported
sugar to free up stocks for export.
(6.) The United States and the EU have reached an accord on
banana import rules (Edward Alden and Deborah Hargreaves, April 12,
2001). Caribbean countries will receive a smaller quota than was
promised, but it is higher than current sales. However, EU countries
and the European parliament have to approve the accord.
(7.) Although some analysts cast doubt on the reliability of the
data, the government of Barbados (Development Plan 1969-1972, 7)
reported that "tourist spending generated about 43 percent of
national income in Barbados in 1967 ... about 30 percent of total
tax revenue ... almost BD$17 million in wages ... [and about]
BD$70-$80 million invested in accommodation." The plan also noted
that "sugar [was] no longer able to perform its traditional function
of [leading] income generator...." (Development Plan 1969-1972, 7).
(8.) When he recaptured the government in 1989, Manley expressed
his commitment to the market-oriented approach to development and
the party has not reverted to its socialist policies of the 1970s.
(9.) This impressive growth statistic might be attributed to the
fact that the Guyanese economy was growing from a very low base.
(10.) The negative growth rate between 1990 and 1997 could be
attributed in part to the deep recession from 1990 to 1992.
(11.) See Manley (1987, 50-54) for a full discussion of the
bauxite levy.
(12.) Guyana and Jamaica were some of the countries that formed a
cartel of bauxite-producing countries in 1974 with the purpose of
improving their bargaining power with the bauxite multinational
corporations.
(13.) Rice flour is a staple in the diet of a country such as
Thailand, which has never been colonized.
(14.) The "Dutch Disease" occurs when a nation's currency
appreciates because of a high foreign demand for a domestic natural
resource and results in the loss of international competitiveness in
other sectors. After the Netherlands developed its natural gas
industry, the Dutch florin appreciated and caused the industrial
sector of that country to lose its international competitiveness.
(15.) In a two-commodity, two-factor world, the Rybcznski theorem
states that, assuming commodity prices remain constant, an increase
in the supply of one factor (the supply of the other factor
remaining unchanged) will result in an absolute increase in the
output of the commodity that uses intensively the factor that has
increased and an absolute decline in the output of the other
commodity.
(16.) Of the 162 countries for which the United Nations
Development Programme generated a human development index (HDI) in
an attempt to measure a country's social development, Indonesia
ranked 102nd, Nigeria 136th, and the Democratic Republic of Congo
142nd. The corresponding HDI values were 0.677, 0.455, and 0.429
respectively (United Nations Development Programme 2001).
(17.) About 38 percent of long-stay visitors to Barbados return
within five years. (This information was provided by the Caribbean
Tourism Organization, Barbados).
(18.) Demas' view of tourism may help to explain why Trinidad and
Tobago, whose resource base is considered mote conducive to the
development of heavy industry than that of Barbados, did not try to
encourage export tourism. It may also help to explain why that
country built an industrial complex at Point Lisas.
(19.) See Economist, "Travel and Tourism: A Survey," January 10,
1998, for a discussion of global tourism.
(20.) Eric Fischl's "A Visit To/A Visit From/The Island" portrays
the negative side of Caribbean tourism. The painter shows "sun-lust'
tourists blissfully unaware of the struggles many of the black
population face in trying to earn a living. The two halves of the
diptych are linked by the storm clouds that bring destruction to the
island natives.
(21.) In 1998, the tourism sector provided direct and indirect
employment for about 31,800 persons, or 27 percent of all
employment; long-stay visitor expenditure was US$690 million, or 54
percent of all exports of goods and services; and tourism
contributed about US$154 million to government revenue, or 20
percent of all government revenues. (This information was provided
by the Caribbean Tourism Association, Barbados.)
(22.) An exception to the party-cum-union relationship in the
Caribbean is the People's National Movement in Trinidad and Tobago,
founded by Dr Eric Williams (Wallace 1977).
(23.) See Codrington 1999 for a discussion of the three protocols
signed by the public sector, the private sector, and the trades
unions.
(24.) The following paragraphs draw on Griffith 1994, 43-44.
References
Alden, Edward, and Deborah Hargreaves. "US and EU Agree on Banana
Imports Trade Deal." Financial Times, April 12, 2001. Internet:
<http://web.lexis-nexis.co/universe/doc...A1&_md5=710c44140f252b7-ceb
ba862072164d53>.
Ambursley, Fitzroy. "Jamaica: From Michael Manley to Edward
Seaga." In Crisis in the Caribbean, edited by Fitzroy Ambursley and
Robin Cohen. London: Heinemann, 1983, 72-104.
Ayres, C. E. The Theory of Economic Progress. New York: Schocken
Books. 1962.
Baber, C., and H. Jeffrey. Guyana: Polities, Economics, and
Society. London: Frances Pinter, 1996.
Barbados Ministry of Finance and Economic Affairs. "Barbados
Economic and Social Report 1998."
Barbados Nation. "Four-pronged Protection Plan." Internet:
<http//www.nationsnews.com/StoryView.cfm?Record=
11748&Section=LO>, March 15, 2001.
-----. "Protocol Praised," Internet:
<http://www.nationsnews.com/templates/nation_news_view,cfm?Record=159
16&Section=LO>, May 2, 2000.
Beckford, George L. Persistent Poverty: Underdevelopment in
Plantation Economies of the Third World. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1972.
Brotherson, Festus. "PNC's Political Paradox." Caribbean Contact.
March 1989, 7.
Caribbean Contact. "Hoyte Seeks To Rebuild Economy." January
1989, 6.
Caribbean Development Bank, "Social and Economic Indicators
1996."
-----. "Annual Report 1997."
Caribbean Tourism Organization. "Caribbean Tourism Statistical
Report 1995." Barbados, 1995.
Central Bank of Barbados. "Annual Statistical Digest 1999."
-----. "Annual Statistical Digest 1996."
Codrington, Harold. "Social Partnerships in Economic Development:
Lessons from the Barbados Experience." A paper presented at the
Tenth Annual Convention of the Congress of Political Economists,
Tallin, Estonia, July 13-17, 1999.
Commonwealth Caribbean Regional Secretariat. "From Carifta to
Caribbean Community." Georgetown, Guyana, 1972.
Demas, William G. The Economics of Development in Small Countries
with Special Reference to the Caribbean. Montreal: McGill University
Press, 1965.
Dunning, John H. "Globalization and the New Geography of Foreign
Direct Investment." In The Political Economy of Globalization,
edited by Ngaire Woods, 20-53. New York: St. Martin's Press, 2000.
Economist. "Travel and Tourism: A Survey." January 10, 1998.
Farrell, Trevor. "Why--AT&T Crisis?" Caribbean Contact.
February 1986, 8.
Fieldhouse, D. K. Colonialism 1870-1945: An Introduction. New
York: St. Martin's Press, 1981.
Francis-Hinds, Suzanne. "Seaga and Jamaica's Exporters."
Caribbean Contact. March 1982, 6.
Girvan, Norman. Foreign Capital and Economic Underdevelopment in
Jamaica. Jamaica: Institute of Social and Economic Research, 1971.
Government of Barbados. "Development Plan 1969-1972." Barbados.
-----. "Development Plan 1988-93." Barbados.
Griffith, Winston. "Appropriate
Economic Theory for the Caribbean." In The Caribbean in the Global
Political Economy, edited by Hilbourne Watson, 31-48. Boulder, Cob.:
Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1994.
Hagelberg, G. B. "Some Current Questions of Sugar Policy and
Implementation in Barbados." Economic Review, Central Bank of
Barbados 12 no. 1 (June 1985): 23-30.
Hawken, Paul, Amory Lovins, and L. Hunter Lovins. Natural
Capitalism: Creating the Next Industrial Revolution. Boston: Little,
Brown and Company, 1999.
International Labour Organization. "Yearbook of Labour
Statistics." Geneva, 1998.
-----. "Yearbook of Labour Statistics." Geneva, 1995.
Jamaica Gleaner. "Overseas Press Hurts Tourism." Internet:
Jamaica Gleaner
<wysiwyg://12/http://www.jmaica-gleaner.com/gleaner/20010423/news/new
s3.html>, April 23, 2001.
Kaufman, Michael. Jamaica under Manley: Dilemmas of Socialism and
Democracy. London: Zed Books, 1985.
Kempadoo, Kamala, ed. Sun, Sex, and Gold: Tourism and Sex Work in
the Caribbean. Lanham, Md.: Rowan & Littlefield Publishers,
Inc., 1999.
Latin American Bureau. Guyana: Fraudulent Revolution. London,
1984.
Lewis, Arthur W. "Education and Economic Development." Social and
Economic Studies 10, no. 2 (1961): 113- 127.
Mackoon, Lindsay. "T&T Wooing Foreign Investors." Caribbean
Contact. October 1987a, 2.
-----. "T&T State Enterprises to Be Assessed." Caribbean
Contact. June 1987b, 2.
-----. "A Climate of Apathy." Caribbean Contact. January 1989, 5.
Manley, Michael. The Politics of Change: A Jamaican Testament.
London: Andre Deutsch, 1974.
-----. Jamaica: Struggle in the Periphery. London: Third World
Media Ltd, 1982.
-----. Up the Down Escalator. Washington, D.C.: Howard University
Press, 1987.
McIntyre, Sir Alister. "High Costs of Production Hurting Region."
Internet: Barbados Daily Nation, <>, October 24, 2000.
McShane, Owen. "The Curse Of Natural Resources." Far Eastern
Economic Review (October 1995): 40.
Meier, Gerald M. "Trade as an 'Engine of Growth'--Note." In
Leading Issues in Economic Development, 4th edition, edited by
Gerald M. Meier. New York: Oxford University Press, 1984, 489-492.
Neale, Walter C. "Institutions." Journal of Economic Issues 21,
no. 3 (September 1987): 1177-1206.
Olson, Mancur. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press, 1982.
Passell, Peter, "The Curse of Natural Resources. They Can Keep a
Country Poor." New York Times, September 21, 1995, D2.
Phillips, Michael M. "In Africa, Resources Have Their Downside."
Wall Street Journal, June 19, 2000, A1.
Ranis, Gustav. "Challenges and Opportunities Posed by Asia's
Superexporters: Implications for Manufactured Exports from Latin
America." Reprinted in Latin America's Economic Development:
Confronting Crisis, 2nd edition, edited by James L. Dietz. Boulder,
Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1995, 167-189.
Rother, Larry. "A Tiger in a Sea of Pussy Cats." New York Times,
September 4, 1998, C1.
Sandiford, L. Erskine. "Financial Statement and Budgetary
Proposals." March 15, 1993.
Singh, Rickey. "Barbados at 21: Celebration of Progress."
Caribbean Contact. December 1987, 6.
Stotsky, Janet, Esther Suss, and Stephen Tokarick. "Trade
Liberalization in the Caribbean." Finance & Development 37, no.
2 (June 2000): 22-5.
Thomas, Clive. "State Capitalism in Guyana: an Assessment of
Burnham's Co-operative Socialist Republic." In Crisis in the
Caribbean, edited by Fitzroy Ambursley and Robin Cohen. London:
Heinemano, 1983, 27-48.
United Nations Development Programme. "Human Development Report
1999."
"Human Development Report 2001."
United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the
Caribbean. "Statistical Yearbook for Latin America and the
Caribbean." 1998.
United Nations. Global Outlook 2000: An Economic, Social and
Environmental Perspective. United Nations, 1990.
Veblen, Thorstein. The Theory of the Leisure Class. [1899.]
Reprint, New York: Mentor Book, 1953.
Wallace, Elizabeth. The British Caribbean: From the Decline of
Colonialism to the End of Federation. Toronto: Toronto University
Press, 1977.
Weekend Nation. "PM, Benn in Radio Clash over Impasse." February
26, 1999, p. 3.
Williams, Eric E. From Columbus To Castro: The History of the
Caribbean 1492-1969. New York: Harper & Row, Publishers, 1970.
-----. "An Address at the Start of Construction of the Iron/Steel
Complex, Point Lisas." In Forged from the Love of Liberty: Selected
Speeches of Dr. Eric Williams, edited by Paul K. Sutton. Trinidad:
Longman Caribbean, 1981, 81-85.
World Bank. World Bank Atlas (various issues). Washington, D.C.
-----. "World Development Report 1998/1999." Washington, D.C.,
1999.
Table 1
Percentage Contribution of Selected Sectors to GDP 1997
Agriculture Manufacturing Mining Tourism
Barbados 4.3 (a) 5.1 0.5 (b) 42.8 (g)
Guyana 36.4 (a) 3.1 (c) 14.6 (b) 9.2 (g)
Jamaica 8.0 (a) 16.0 5.6 (b) 23.5 (g)
Trinidad and Tobago 2.1 7.6 (e) 28.3 (f) 1.7 (h)
Source: Central Bank of Barbados, Annual Statistical Digest 1999;
caribbean Tourism Organization, Caribbean Tourism Statistical Report
1995.
(a)Includes fishing.
(b)Includes quarrying.
(c)Includes electricity, gas and water
(d)Includes forestry and fishing.
(e)Excludes oil refining and petrochemical industries.
(f)Petroleum.
(g)Tourism expenditures for 1995.
(h)Tourism expenditures for 1994.
Table 2
Real Average Annual Growth of GNP per Capita
Barbados Guyana Jamaica Trinidad & Tobago
1970-1979 2.1 0.0 -3.7 4.5
1980-1990 1.4 -3.2 -0.4 -6.0
1999-1997 -0.9 12.9 0.8 1.4
Sources: World Bank, World Bank Atlas (various years), Washington, D.C.
Table 3
Selected Social Indicators
Barbados Guyana Jamaica Trinidad and Tobago
Life expectancy at
birth (years)
1970 68.5 59.6 68.3 65.5
1997 76.4 64.4 74.8 73.8
Infant mortality rate
(per 1,000 live births)
1970 40 81 47 49
1997 11 59 10 15
Under five mortality
rate (per 1,000 live
births)
1970 54 101 62 57
1997 12 82 11 17
Adult literacy rate
(%)
1997 97.6 98.1 85.5 97.8
Net enrollment ratio--
primary (as a percentage
of relevant age group)
1997 97.4 92.8 95.6 99.5
Net enrollement ratio--
secondary (as a
percentage of relevant
age group)
1997 85.7 74.9 69.8 71.5
Daily per capita
supply of calories
1970 2,805 2,224 2,483
1996 3,207 2,392 2,575
Daily per capita supply
of protein (total)
grams
1996 87.9 63.5 61.7 63.1
Personal computers
per 1,000 persons
1997 57.5 -- 4.6 20.0
Telephone main
lines per 1,000
persons
1997 404 60 140 190
Source: United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report
1999; World Bank Atlas 1999, Washington, D.C.
Table 4
Number of Strikes and Lockouts
Year Barbados Guyana Trinidad and Tobago
1985 5 718 45
1986 2 453 16
1987 7 497 10
1988 10 349 11
1989 12 138 24
1990 17 329 14
1991 10 307 16
1992 12 258 17
1993 5 475 24
1994 2 468 13
1995 8 422 15
Sources: International Labour Organization, Yearbook of
Labour Statistics 1995, 1998.
Table 5
Workdays Not Worked (in Thousands)
Year Barbados Guyana Trinidad and Tobago
1985 5.289 -- 76.554
1986 0.106 -- 80.707
1987 2.32 31.449 30.824
1988 0.697 232.595 7.102
1989 3.931 686.359 91.07
1990 1.754 244.498 10.439
1991 0.643 110.871 15.673
1992 0 126.747 69.258
1993 0.038 129.344 29.099
1994 0.019 90.138 14.954
1995 0.334 81.369 209.742
Source: International Labour Organization, Yearbook of Labour Statistics
1995 and 1998.
Table 6
Consumer Price Indices
Year Barbados Jamaica Trinidad and Tobago
1985 83.2 54.1 62.9
1986 84.3 62.1 67.7
1987 87.2 66.3 75.0
1988 91.4 71.7 80.0
1989 97.1 82.4 90.1
1990 100.0 100.0 100.0
1991 106.3 151.1 103.8
1992 112.7 267.9 110.6
1993 114.0 327.0 122.5
1994 114.1 441.7 133.2
1995 103.0 529.7 140.3
1996 105.6 669.5 144.9
Source: International Labour Organization, Yearbook of Labour Statistics
1995 and 1998.
The author is in the Department of Economic, Bucknell University,
Lewisburg, Pennsylvania, USA. An earlier version of this article was
presented at the Eleventh Annual Convention of the Congress of
Political Economists, Imperial College, London, England, August
6-12, 2000. The author wishes to thank two referees for their
helpful comments. |