It
is an interesting and somewhat daunting task to write an essay about economic
theory for an interdisciplinary audience. If
a field of study only has to meet the dictionary definition of the word interdisciplinary
to actually be considered interdisciplinary —“involving two or more
academic disciplines”[1]—then
economics certainly qualifies. Economics
has a distinct quantitative focus and draws heavily from disciplines such as
math and statistics. Its
underpinnings are rooted in political philosophy and more recent specialty areas
make extensive use of law, history, psychology, sociology, and international
studies.
The
Foreward to various editions of the Journal
of Interdisciplinary Education suggests a meaning of the word interdisciplinary
that is considerably more complicated, however, and possibly casts a bit of
doubt as to whether economics is as interdisciplinary as perhaps it ought to be.
The issue on Ecology of Education
(1997, p. 5), e.g., speaks of “the interrelatedness of all creation.” The
issue on Unity Through Diversity
(2000, p. v.) suggests that, “Education grounded in nonviolence, social and
economic justice, political justice that recognizes and promotes human rights,
and ecological justice is the ethical responsibility of educators from
pre-school through university.” It goes on to state that, “Educators have an
ethical responsibility to promote an understanding of how humans relate to all
of creation. The three C’s—caring, compassion, and commitment—must be
rooted in hope, understanding and love.” With few exceptions, a majority of
these concepts simply do not appear in economics textbooks. In a review of the
indexes of 21 principles of economics textbooks, the word justice
appeared twice and the expression ethical
issues appeared twice. Words or concepts such as humanity, human rights, nonviolence,
ecology, love, commitment, or community, do not appear at all. The
word human appears in every textbook,
but only in the context of human capital.
Robert Sexton’s definition of human capital in his principles textbook
(1999, p. 466), “People used as resources in production,” seems the
antithesis of most of the above concepts.
Among
the more important core concepts to economists are economic
growth, efficiency, and comparative advantage. These three, in fact, lie at the heart of all modern
macroeconomic policy deliberations. Underlying these concepts, of course, is the
assumption of the primacy of individual initiative and rationality in a free
market setting, implying that the majority of all human activities are
undertaken to maximize our well being. McEachern (Economics 5th ed., 2000), for example, refers to us as
having wants or desires that are “virtually unlimited (p.2).”
Burns and Stone (Economics 5th ed., 1992) describe our human wants as
“virtually unlimited” and “insatiable (p. 5).” Frank and Bernanke (Principles
of Economics, 2001) state that we have “boundless needs and wants
(p.4).”
If
these books are reasonably accurate in describing human behavior—that
maximizing consumption is the goal of society—then supporting concepts like
economic growth, efficiency, and comparative advantage make perfect sense.
If society is organized to meet the needs of consumers with
“insatiable” demands, then Gross Domestic Product (GDP)[2],
a measure of the value of all goods
and services produced, is a logical way to measure our collective well being.
Furthermore, if the goal is to maximize GDP (or its growth rate), then
you could imagine that the wasteful use of scarce resources in the production of
a product, or not producing something using the lowest possible cost technique
would certainly not be desirable.
It
is the purpose of this analysis to examine 1) the theories and assumptions of
economic growth, efficiency, and comparative advantage, and how well they
correlate with real world outcomes, and 2) the impacts on society of having
these three concepts at the core of economic policy making. A major point to be
made in the analysis that follows is that these three concepts are possibly too
narrow to use as guide-posts for all societies in all places, at all times.
In
the following sections there will be three analyses that will address the
appropriateness of these three concepts as policy tools. The first entails a
multi-country empirical analysis of the relationship between economic growth and
a number of social welfare indicators such as literacy, infant mortality rates,
life expectancy, income distribution, caloric intake, and availability of
doctors. Also, because the theory
associated with these three concepts leads policy makers to the conclusion that
for many countries, the way to generate economic growth is to focus on the
production of exports, a second empirical analysis will examine the relationship
between exports and the same list of social welfare indicators mentioned above.
The
third analysis focuses on alternative economic development programs in a small
community in the central highlands of Guatemala, San Lucas Tolimán. On the
surface it might appear that San Lucas appears to be violating a number of
textbook economic axioms. Many of
the programs there do not appear to have been designed with the goal of
maximizing Guatemala’s GDP, nor do they appear to be (economically) efficient
or meet the criteria of comparative advantage.
Upon closer inspection, though, it is argued that if the founder of the
discipline of economics, Adam Smith, from whose work all of the above concepts
originated,[3]
were to walk the streets of San Lucas, he might appreciate the robust little
economy as being exactly what he had in mind when he wrote the Wealth of
Nations over 200 years ago.
These three analyses will be preceded by a section examining some of the theoretical issues related to economic growth, efficiency, and comparative advantage, along with criticisms and statistical evidence from the developing world.
According
to McEachern (2000), economic growth is “arguably the most important criterion
for judging an economy’s performance (p.111).” Samuelson and Nordhaus (1992)
suggest that most nations regard economic growth as “a central economic and
political objective,” and the failure to provide such growth as the primary
reason for the collapse of the Soviet Union and Eastern bloc countries (p. 546).
The popular expression, “a rising tide floats all boats,” is a metaphor for
the good things that come to a society that experiences economic growth.
According to many economists, when the economy is growing, everyone benefits,
rich and poor alike; therefore, growth should be the primary focus of policy
actions, rather than government programs to redistribute income or wealth.
Economic growth as a cure for underdevelopment has long been a primary focus of
World Bank programs. The entire
issue of the World Development Report 2000/2001, published by the World
Bank, is focused on poverty. The Bank argues that the poor need more material
opportunities and that “overall economic growth” along with “market
reforms” are essential for enhancing opportunities” (p.7).
The
market reforms to which the World Bank refers, entail a return to (or possibly
for some countries their first experiment ever with) the orthodoxy of laissez
faire—a hands off approach to the economic organization of society.
There is no need for an activist government to oversee market activities
if the following textbook assumptions hold: 1) producers and consumers of goods
and services are motivated to maximize their well-being, 2) there are
sufficiently large numbers of buyers and sellers in the marketplace, 3) no
barriers to market participation exist, 4) there is adequate access to
information such that rational decision making is facilitated, and 5) the
transaction costs of acting on such information are “reasonable.” Suppose a
corporation decided to overcharge for its products. Rather than needing a governmental watchdog agency to step in
to protect the consumer from this behavior, the presence of other similar
corporations all producing similar products will ensure that the corporation
doing the overcharging will not be successful in this endeavor.
If the corporation’s customers are aware that lower prices exist at its
competitors, and if it is not too costly to get to their locations, then they
will travel to those locations to make their purchases. With falling sales,
because of the loss of its customers, the overcharging corporation will have no
choice but to reduce its prices back into line with those of its competitors.
This is an example of what Adam Smith referred to as the “invisible hand of
the market place” (2000, p. 485).
Note
the importance of consumers in the above example. According to textbook theory,
consumers have the power to compete on equal terms with producers.
Nothing will be produced that is not desired in the first place.
If consumers don’t want a product, or they don’t want it at a certain
price, it is simply not going to sell. Therefore, economic growth, by
definition, is a positive thing. The
increase in the nation’s output of goods and services occurs only because
producers respond to the needs and wants of consumers.
In
a society in which the actions of profit maximizing private producers and
utility-maximizing consumers provide the driving force of the economy, economic
growth, according to textbook theory, will occur naturally.
And the growth will be facilitated by decisions made with regard to efficiency
and comparative advantage. Textbook definitions of efficiency are
specifically concerned with maximizing output.
McEachern (2000, p. 34) states that “efficiency involves getting the
maximum possible output from available resources.” Case and Fair (2002)
reiterate the concern for the consumer that was noted above.
They state that “an efficient economy is one that produces the things
that people want at least cost.... that the economic system exists to serve the
wants and needs of the people. If resources can be reallocated to make the
people ‘better off,’ then they should be” (p.251).
One of the more widely used concepts of efficiency in economic
decision-making was developed by the Italian economist Wilfredo Pareto. An
economic allocation of goods and services or resources is considered to be Pareto
efficient or Pareto optimal if, in
an attempt to make some group better off, (i.e., to provide them with more
goods, or more resources), others are made worse off in the process.
Such
concepts are not without controversy. The
poor of Africa, Asia, or Latin America who have never visited a doctor, attended
a school, or taken a drink of clean water, or who have no hope of owning their
own land probably take little comfort in the teachings of economic theorists who
contend that the pursuit of economic growth and efficiency goes hand in hand
with serving the wants and needs of the people. As will be discussed in the
analysis below on San Lucas Tolimán, Guatemala, oftentimes, the concept of
Pareto efficiency, rather than serving as a criterion for economic growth,
instead, serves to maintain the status quo.
In a country where land, which is the primary means of production for a
majority of the population, is unevenly divided and extremely scarce, adopting
an efficiency measure such as Pareto optimality, in effect, assures that serious
agrarian reform will never be undertaken. To redistribute even an acre of land from the oligarchy to
poor families would, following the Pareto principle, make one person worse off
and should thus not be considered, regardless of how much better off the
families receiving the land might be.
David
Ricardo’s (1817) Classical Theory of Comparative Advantage states that each
nation is blessed with (or over time has acquired) a set of particular factor
endowments (rich soil, navigable waterways, ideal climate, highly skilled work
force, etc.) that allow it to produce certain products at a lower per unit cost
than its neighbors. For example,
the U.S. has a skilled work force and rich mineral deposits that allow it to
produce cars and computers relatively cheaper than Guatemala could. Guatemala, on the other hand, has rich volcanic soil and a
semi-tropical climate in which it can produce bananas and coffee at much lower
cost than in the US. It would
therefore be more efficient, i.e., less wasteful of scarce resources, for the US
to specialize in the production of cars and computers, and for Guatemala to
specialize in the production of bananas and coffee, than if each country strived
for self-sufficiency in each product.[4]
By focusing a country’s scarce resources only on the products for which it has
a comparative advantage and then freely trading for all other products in the
international market place, each nation’s GDP will be maximized as a result.
The policy implications of this theory, as they have evolved over the
years, are that countries should devote more and more of their resources to the
production of export goods and services as the surest route to development.
Critics
such as Susan George (1990) or David Korten (1995, 1999) argue that Ricardo’s
simple theory has been taken out of its original European context and carried to
extremes by the IMF and World Bank who force borrowing nations to adhere rigidly
to economic strategies that narrowly focus on the production of export products
to the exclusion and detriment of the domestic economy. Such strategies, often
labeled as neo-liberal, include privatization, elimination of government
subsidies and programs, devotion of more land and resources to the production of
export products, discouragement of labor unions, and devaluation of the local
currency in order to make export products more attractive to foreign buyers.
Often a case can be made that attention to some of the above changes
might in fact help to streamline a highly inefficient economy that has come to
rely too heavily on the government for most economic decision making. The former Soviet Union and its eastern bloc allies come
immediately to mind in this regard. But
IMF and World Bank programs are applied in a rather uniform manner to most
countries regardless of their unique circumstances. Such countries may well need to make a number of adjustments
in the direction of a more market-oriented economy, but for the sake of the
general population, a slower transition might be more advantageous than the
instantaneous, shock-therapy approach the IMF usually requires. The case of
Nicaragua is instructive.
After
the elections in 1990 that threw the Sandinistas out of power in Nicaragua, the
new UNO government of Violeta Chamorro immediately signed on to a structural
adjustment program with the IMF. One of its first moves was to eliminate
approximately 10,000 government jobs that were deemed to be wasteful and
inefficient. Unfortunately, no
thought was given as to what these former workers and their families might do,
or where they might live once they lost their means of support.
Economic theory suggests that when dislocations occur, resources will
move toward their highest use in the long run.
Theory says nothing about what is supposed to happen in the short run.
In Nicaragua’s capital city of Managua, many of the laid off workers
and their families found themselves literally living in open fields—vast areas
that were never rebuilt after the 1972 earthquake—in hastily constructed
shacks made of cardboard, discarded pieces of wood, and pallets. I was there on
a visit shortly after the elections and the one lasting memory I have from a
visit to the under-funded children’s hospital was of children with
third-degree burns suffered from fires associated with cooking over open fires.
The hospital administrator told me that many of those kids were living in
the cardboard shacks mentioned above. They
would either accidentally tip over a pot of boiling water on themselves or get
caught in the cooking fire.
In
spite of such detrimental impacts on the population, Nicaragua has strictly
adhered to the IMF’s structural adjustment program.
For example, exports as a percentage of GDP have increased from 25% to
39% over the decade of the 1990s. Its
currency has been devalued by nearly 100%, but none of this has brought any
visible improvement to the country. Its
economy, as measured by GDP per capita shrank continuously over the
decade—from $460 in 1990 to $452 in 1998 (1995 US$) and, among the countries
of Latin America, its social indicators rank near the bottom of the United
Nation’s Human Development Index scale.[5]
Only Guatemala and Haiti are ranked lower. (United Nations Human
Development Report [UNHDR] 2000, Tables 1, 7, and 15).
Ghana
is another example of a country that has faithfully restructured its economy
along the lines dictated by the IMF and World Bank.
In fact it has been under IMF and World Bank tutelage since 1983 and has
been frequently touted by these institutions as a showcase of the benefits that
can come to a country that follows an export-led economic strategy.
As evidence of its adherence to this strategy, the country has nearly
doubled its exports as a percent of GDP over the last decade from 16.9% to 32% (UNHDR
2000, Table 15), and, like Nicaragua, has aggressively devalued its currency by
more than 90%. The Bank’s own statistics, however, suggest that the showcase
may be illusory. Ninety-six out of every 1000 children will not live to see
their 5th birthday. Overall life expectancy is only 60 years and 44%
of the population does not have access to clean water. (WDR, Tables 2 and 7).
Ghana ranks 129th on the UN Human Development Index. The UNHDR
reports that there are only 4 doctors for every 100,000 Ghanaians, and that 31%
of the population cannot read or write. Furthermore, the economic growth that
had been promised has simply not materialized. GDP per capita stood at the end
of the decade of the 1990s at approximately the same level it was when the
country entered into its first IMF standby agreement--$399 (1995 US$). (UNHDR,
Tables 4, 7, and 10).
One
of the problems Ghana is facing, and one that potentially affects all countries
that follow export-led strategies, is that if a majority of developing countries
are being encouraged to increase their export volume, this has the effect of
creating a glut of commodities on world markets.
Economic theory is rarely wrong in predicting that an excess supply of
commodities will drive down their prices. For
various reasons, however, this ever-so-obvious outcome is overlooked when
countries are encouraged by the IMF and World Bank to devote more resources to
exports. In the case of Ghana, a majority of its export commodities have seen
falling prices over the past two decades. The
price of its primary export, cocoa, has fallen over 46%, or 4.1% per year, since
1983. Other important commodities such as gold, copra, tea, and coffee have all
faced serious declines in prices. (International Financial Statistical Yearbook
2000, IMF, pp. 180-1). For a
country to maintain the value of its export earnings in the face of falling
prices, it must increase its output—thus devoting more land and resources to
export production. But the dilemma
it faces is that if all developing countries react to falling prices in the same
way, the glut of commodities on world markets that contributed to falling prices
in the first place is simply expanded, creating a vicious downward commodity
price spiral.
While
a majority of economists see economic growth as a cure for underdevelopment,
there is by no means a consensus of all observers on this issue. At one extreme
is Walter Rostow’s (1960) “stages-of-growth” model, for example. He
suggests that all countries develop along a fairly well scripted time path, each
beginning at some earlier stage of underdevelopment and culminating eventually
in a “high mass consumption” society. To an orthodox economist, a country
that has not yet arrived at the pinnacle of high mass consumption need not be
concerned and turn to the government for assistance, rather, it simply needs to
“stay the course” and continue relying on market signals and private
initiatives.[6]
The
idea that economic growth (not to mention high mass consumption) might be
equated with development is especially controversial if your definition of
development is something along the lines of Walter Rodney’s, instead of Walter
Rostow’s. Rodney (1972) describes a country that is undergoing development as
one in which “its members increase jointly their capacity for dealing with the
environment” (p.4). It is a safe
bet that a sizeable number of the world’s peoples, six decades into the era of
modern approaches to economic development, are still at the stage of learning to
cope with their environment, rather than worshipping at the alter of high mass
consumption. A number of social
indicators from the United Nations Human Development Report (2000)
suggest that this is indeed the case. For
the 34 countries in the Low Human Development category—most of which are in
Africa—citizens can expect to live only 51 years.
In comparison, the number one ranked country in the High Human
Development category, Canada, has a life expectancy of 79 years. For every 1000
live births in these 34 countries, 105 infants will die and 167 will not make it
to age five (Canada: 6 and 6, respectively). In those same countries 51% cannot
read or write (Canada: near 0%), and 39% do not have access to safe water
(Canada: near 0%). People in need
of a doctor in those countries will likely have difficulty finding one given
that there are only 27 doctors per 100,000 people on average (Canada: 221 per
100,000) (Tables 4, 9, and 10).
What
is especially disturbing about these statistics is that many of these countries
are, in fact, experiencing economic growth. Using the yardstick of GDP per
capita (1995 US$), the 34 Low Human Development countries averaged 3.8% growth
per year from 1975-1998. Compare
this to Canada: 1.5% or the United States: 1.9%.
On a dollar basis though, these 34 countries have an average GDP of only
$980. Compare to Canada: $20,458 or the United States: $29,683. The 93 countries
in the Medium Human Development category have grown even faster—6.2%, but
their average GDP per capita is only $3460. (UNHDR 2000, Table 7).
Clearly, something has gone wrong along the way in these countries that
has caused a disconnect between growth and development. Barnet and Müller, in
their book Global Reach (1974),
suggest that “poor countries are poor because they are deficient in what
economists call capital stock: that is, they lack the tangible (and expensive)
infrastructures that enable modern developed societies to function and to create
more wealth--roads, communications systems, schools, machines and factories.
But capital stock, unlike mushrooms, does not grow wild. Its appearance at
a particular time and place is the result of specific human decisions about
investment taken in the past. If a country is poor in wealth-producing
structures (capital stock), it is because whoever controlled wealth in that
country decided to invest their finance capital in something else or somewhere
else (pp. 134-135).”[7]
Among the more glaring indicators that the decisions by a country’s
elite to invest elsewhere can lead to gross inequities in poor countries are
income distribution figures. For
the Low Human Development countries, the richest 20% of all income earners
receive 50% of their countries’ incomes, on average.
For the Medium Human Development countries, the figure is even higher:
52%. Poverty rates are another
indicator of the impacts of such investment decisions. In the Low Human
Development countries 49.4% of the population, on average, live below their
respective nations’ poverty lines. The figure for the Medium Human Development
countries is 28.8% (UNHDR 2000, Table 4).
One
final disturbing thought about these countries is that they have borrowed
heavily--from governments, private banks, the IMF, and World Bank—to
facilitate their pursuit of economic growth, but apparently have accomplished
very little with their funds. In
1990 Susan George titled her book A Fate
Worse Than Debt in response to the fact that Third World debt had hit $1
trillion dollars and no end appeared in sight.
According to the World Bank’s latest figures (1998), developing country
external debt has now surpassed $2.5 trillion (WDR 2000/2001, Table 21).
The
issues in this section suggest that economic theory and real world outcomes
don’t always have a strong correlation. According
to David Korten (1995), market players (policy makers, CEOs, etc.) selectively
choose certain theoretical concepts to suit their needs and ignore others.
For example, he reminds us that according to theory, efficient market
outcomes are obtained only if all of the costs of production are included in the
producer’s selling price. But he suggests that this is rarely the case, as
most companies externalize these costs onto the public, the environment, and
other countries (pp. 74-80).[8]
Wilber and Jameson (1988) offer criticism of a different sort. They argue
that economists are so wedded to their theories—Wilber and Jameson refer to
them as paradigms—“that empirical disconfirmation of some particular
hypothesis is almost automatically rejected” (p. 4). Adherents to Rostow’s stages
of growth approach to development, for example, would not consider any of
the above depressing social statistics as an “empirical disconfirmation” of
the hypothesis that economic growth is beneficial to the well being of these
countries. Rather, they would point out that either not enough time has passed
and that further strict adherence to an export-led strategy is needed, or that
extenuating circumstances, such as a government that has not been willing to
sufficiently reduce its presence in the marketplace, are preventing the normal
development process that follows from economic growth to take place.
The
lack of theoretical consensus on these matters highlights the need for an
objective look. Allowing the data from the developing world itself to speak to
the issue of whether or not its societies have benefited from attention to
economic growth and exports should prove useful. The following section
empirically examines the correlation between economic growth (as well as
exports) and a variety of social welfare indicators in the developing world to
see exactly how well countries are doing that have pursued strategies designed
to generate high rates of economic growth.
In
this section, two hypotheses are tested that follow from the previous
theoretical discussion: 1) Economic
growth is positively correlated with social welfare, and 2) Export
production is positively correlated with social welfare. Ideally, one
might want to establish causality, rather than simple correlation, running from
economic growth (or exports) to the various social welfare indicators. This is a
complex undertaking, however, especially if one seeks to verify that economic
growth or exports are the “agents” that specifically bring about a change in
any of the social welfare indicators, or in other words, if one seeks to
establish causality in the dictionary sense of the word.
Statistical causality on the other hand, is more manageable, but
still requires that the following minimal conditions hold: 1) there must be
concomitant variation between variables, such as correlation or covariation, 2)
there must be a time dimension, e.g., one event precedes another event, and 3)
one must be able to reasonably rule out that an additional event is not
influencing your primary variables of concern.[9]
So, simple correlation may not be sufficient for a researcher to claim
that economic growth or export sales improve social welfare in a statistically
causal sense, but it is necessary that such simple correlation exist in
the first place. If the researcher cannot first establish simple correlation,
then further analysis of causality is destined to be a fruitless exercise.
The statistical measure used to establish correlation is the correlation coefficient (r).
, where cov(X,Y) is the covariance
of X and Y, and σX and σY are the standard
deviations of X and Y. By construction, -1 ≤ r ≤1. The case in which r = 1 would indicate a perfectly positive
correlation. In other words, increases in X are always associated with
increases in Y. r = -1 would indicate a perfectly negative correlation, i.e.,
increases in X are always associated with decreases in Y.
r = 0 would indicate no relationship.
According to Younger (1979, pp. 243-4) a value halfway between 0 and 1
(or –1),
1/2, would indicate a “moderate” relationship.
1/4 would indicate a “moderately weak” relationship, and
3/4 would indicate a “moderately strong” relationship.
The
variables used in the analysis, their definitions, their sources, and the sign
of their expected correlation with both GDP and exports (on the basis of
orthodox theory) are listed in Table 1:
Variable |
Definition |
Source |
Sign of expected correlation with GDP and Exports |
GDP |
GDP per capita (1995 US$) Average annual rate of change (%) 1975-98 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 8 |
n/a |
Exports |
Exports of goods and services (as % of GDP), change from 1990-1998 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 15 |
n/a |
Life expectancy |
Life expectancy at birth in years, Percentage change 1970-2000* |
UNHDR 2000, Table 9 |
+ |
Infant mortality rate |
Infant Mortality Rate (per 1000 live births), Percentage change 1970-1998 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 9 |
- |
Literacy rate |
Adult literacy rate (% age 15 and above who can read and write) 1998 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 11 |
+ |
Female literacy rate |
Female literacy rate (% age 15 and above who can read and write) 1998 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 28 |
+ |
Doctors |
Doctors (per 100,000 people) 1992-95 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 10 |
+ |
Calories |
Daily per capita supply of calories, Percentage change 1970-1997 |
UNHDR 2000, Table 23 |
+ |
Income distribution |
Gini index: 0 = perfectly equal distribution, 100 = perfectly unequal distribution. Based on most recent survey year. |
WDR 2000/2001, Table 5 |
? |
Notes: UNHDR 2000 is the United Nations Human Development Report 2000. WDR is the World Bank’s World Development Report 2000/2001. All UN data came from the UNHDR on-line statistical annex: http://www.undp.org/hdro/statistics.html
* The data used in the calculation of the life expectancy growth rate are based on average life expectancies in the periods: 1970-75 and 1995-2000.
In
an effort to keep the statistical analysis manageable, verifiable, and
replicable, all data come from either the UN Human Development Report 2000
or the World Bank World Development Report 2000/2001. A comment on the
samples used to construct the correlation coefficients is necessary. The UNHDR
reports data from 174 countries. The
WDR reports data from 132 countries. Not
surprisingly, there are a number of countries that for one reason or other do
not have entries for certain categories. Some
are too new, some have difficulty collecting the data, etc.
Therefore, there is a wide range of sample sizes.
For example, 160 countries (117 for just the medium and low human
development categories) reported data on both infant mortality rates and GDP per
capita, but only 104 countries (76 for just the medium and low human development
categories) reported data on both exports and income distribution. Rather than
attempt to pare the sample size down to a common number of countries for all
correlation calculations, I used the largest sample size possible in making each
calculation. It didn’t make sense to lose the valuable information about the
relationship on GDP and life expectancy, e.g., from 56 countries just because
those countries don’t report Gini coefficients on income distribution.
The specific countries used in every correlation coefficient calculation
are available upon request.
Also, for every social welfare indicator category to be compared to GDP or exports, a correlation coefficient was generated for all countries (reporting data) in the Low, Medium, and High Human Development categories (ALL) as reported in the UNHDR. Then the High Human Development countries were eliminated and a correlation coefficient for the Medium and Low Human Development countries combined (L-M) was generated. The purpose is to see if there is a difference in the manner in which economic growth and exports affect social indicators of the rich vs. the poorer countries.
This
is a cross sectional study by necessity. As the data permits, the variables were
transformed to give the analysis a long run focus. Rather than compare current
GDP and current life expectancy, for example, the variables were transformed
into long-term growth rates. In cases where data are only available for a single
recent period, e.g., literacy rates (1998), it still makes sense to compare this
number to the long-run GDP growth rate. If, in fact, economic growth has a beneficial effect on
literacy rates (i.e., higher growth leads to higher incomes and the means to
spend more money on education), then the accumulated effects of 23 years of GDP
growth should exhibit a positive correlation with 1998’s literacy rate.
On the other hand, export data are only available from 1990-98.
It doesn’t make sense that export growth during the 1990s would have an
impact on life expectancy, infant mortality, or calorie consumption over a
period from the 1970s to the present. Therefore,
for these three categories, the comparison is for the most recent years for
which data are available: 1995-2000 for life expectancy, 1998 for infant
mortality, and 1997 for calories.
Column
four in Table 1 contains the expected signs of the correlations of each social
indicator with both GDP and exports. The
previous section made the general theoretical argument that increased economic
growth, as well as increased export sales would be beneficial to social welfare.
In the case of life expectancy, this beneficial effect results from the
additional income generated from higher GDP growth or export sales that allow a
nation to gain access to greater quantities and better quality of food, health
care, clean water, education, and other infrastructural necessities, all of
which are assumed to extend life expectancy. In the case of the infant morality
rate, the beneficial effect shows up as a negative sign if increases in GDP and
exports result in a lowering of this rate.
The infant mortality rate should improve for the same reasons as life
expectancy, with benefits coming particularly from improvements in women’s
education, health care, and nutrition. The two literacy rates should have a
positive relationship with GDP and exports if some of the additional income that
results flows in the direction of education. To the extent that gender
discrimination still exists, then one would expect the female literacy rate to
have a smaller correlation with GDP and exports than the overall literacy rate. The correlation of doctors and GDP and exports should be
positive for many of the same reasons already mentioned above: additional income
flowing to health care and education. Regarding calories, orthodox theory would
suggest a positive correlation for many of the same reasons already mentioned.
Non-orthodox theorists, on the other hand, would be quick to point out
that the more export-driven is an economy, the fewer resources are available for
domestic food production. The
export agricultural sector may be the driving engine of an apparently healthy
economy that, in actuality, is doing a poor job of feeding its citizens.
Finally, there is a question mark in the box for the income distribution
category. A rising economic tide
may or may not float the boats of all members of society.
Orthodox theorists would assume everyone benefits from the general
prosperity associated with economic growth. Critics, though, are not so
sanguine. However, even if the
orthodoxy is correct, that all of the citizens of a country benefit from
economic growth and export sales, there is no reason to assume that the poor
might gain at the expense of the rich. The distribution of income could still
worsen even as the economy grows. Thus, this correlation could be positive or negative, but it
is likely to be weak, one way or the other.
The
correlation results are presented below in Table 2:
GDP |
||||
|
All countries (ALL) |
Low and medium human development countries (L-M) |
||
|
r |
sample size (n) |
r |
sample size (n) |
Life expectancy |
.20* |
160 |
.33* |
117 |
Infant mortality rate |
-.43* |
160 |
-.38* |
117 |
Literacy rate |
.24* |
125 |
.13 |
104 |
Female literacy rate |
.09 |
124 |
-.02 |
104 |
Doctors |
-.25* |
146 |
-.52* |
109 |
Calories |
.31* |
140 |
.43* |
95 |
Income distribution |
-.03 |
105 |
-.13 |
77 |
|
||||
Exports |
||||
|
All countries (ALL) |
Low and medium human development countries (L-M) |
||
|
r |
sample size (n) |
r |
sample size (n) |
Life expectancy |
-.05 |
139 |
-.05 |
95 |
Infant mortality rate |
.08 |
148 |
.09 |
104 |
Literacy rate |
.005 |
112 |
.07 |
96 |
Female literacy rate |
-.003 |
112 |
.06 |
96 |
Doctors |
-.09 |
128 |
-.19 |
97 |
Calories |
-.04 |
129 |
-.09 |
96 |
Income distribution |
.01 |
104 |
.01 |
76 |
Note: Asterisks indicate significance at the 5% level.[10]
If,
in fact, the policy goal variables of economic growth and exports are associated
with the positive social outcomes that theory and policy makers suggest, then
one might expect a correlation coefficient of .5 or greater. In other words, one
would hope for at least a “moderate,” or possibly a “moderately strong”
relationship. By this criterion, then, the results in Table 2 collectively are
not very supportive of the two hypotheses. There is only a single correlation
coefficient larger (in absolute value) than .5, and it happens to be the wrong
sign (doctors: -.52). While many of
the coefficients on GDP are significant, none are significant for exports.
In
the first half of the table are GDP correlations. The coefficients for the
category, life expectancy, have the correct sign for the two samples (ALL and
L-M) and are statistically significant, but the values of .20 and .33 suggest
only a moderately weak relationship. The
coefficients for infant mortality, -.43 and -.38, have the correct sign, are
statistically significant, but also suggest only a moderately weak relationship.
The coefficients for the literacy rate, .24 and .13, indicate a weak
relationship, at best. Note that the coefficient for the L-M countries is only
about half of that of ALL countries (and insignificant), indicating that when
the rich countries are left out of the sample, the correlation of economic
growth and literacy is seriously weakened. The coefficients for the female
literacy rate, .09 and -.02, are small and statistically insignificant. In
comparison to the results for overall literacy, these results suggest that well
into the post-modern era, there are apparently still global forces at work that
act to prevent the few positive effects of economic growth on literacy that were
noted above to spill over to significantly affect women. The coefficients for
the category, doctors, -.25 and -.52, have the opposite signs of what theory
would predict. The coefficient for the L-M countries is more than double the
coefficient for ALL countries, a result that does not bode well for the future
health of the developing world. The coefficients for the category, calories,
have the correct sign and are statistically significant, though the values, .31
and .43, suggest once again only a moderately weak relationship. Finally, the
coefficients for income distribution, -.03 and -.13, shed very little light on
the uncertain relationship between economic growth and income distribution.
It appears that the spread between rich and poor narrows as economic
growth occurs, however, both values are extremely small and statistically
insignificant.
The
results for exports are even less impressive than those for GDP. The
coefficients are extremely small, and nearly half have the opposite sign as
predicted. However, as noted above,
none are statistically significant.
This
analysis provides only modest support for the notion that economic growth is
correlated with improvements in social welfare. In some categories, such as
doctors per population and female literacy in developing countries, the
relationship is actually the opposite of what theory would predict. In the case of the hypothesis that increases in export
production are correlated with improvements in social welfare, there was
absolutely no statistically significant evidence in support of this notion.
Based on these results, it cannot be stated with any certainty that
theoretical predictions about the benefits of economic growth or an
export-oriented economy are closely aligned with evidence from the real world.
The
following analysis offers a glimpse of a small-scale model of economic
development that has a genuine concern for social and human welfare at its core,
rather than a concern for economic growth or export production.
Economics
as if People Mattered:[11] Capitalism With a Small
“c” in San Lucas Tolimán
Among
the countries of Latin America, Guatemala is near the bottom of the United
Nation’s Human Development Index; only Haiti ranks lower. The country has been under IMF and World Bank tutelage for over two
decades now, and is seriously committed to export-led economic growth. During
this time, it has diversified its traditional exports of coffee, bananas, sugar,
cotton, and beef to include “non-traditional” crops such as snow peas,
cauliflower, and broccoli, as well as the myriad of textiles and small goods
produced in the growing maquiladora industry. During the troubled decade
of the 1980s, when the country was experiencing civil war, exports actually fell
at an average annual rate of –1.8%. Since
1990, however, they have increased at an annual average rate of 6.4% (WDR
2000/2001Table 11). Exports currently represent nearly 19% of the country’s
GDP (UNHDR 2000 Table 15). Unfortunately, though, this attention to exports does
not seem to have had much impact on Guatemala’s standard of living. Its GDP
per capita of $1533 (1995 US$) in 1998 is actually less than it was before the
country signed on to the banks’ programs (1980: GDP = $1598) (UNHDR 2000 Table
7).
As
bad as those figures seem, given the vast gulf between rich and poor in
Guatemala, they are not particularly meaningful. There are only three countries
in the world with a more highly skewed distribution of income than Guatemala.
The top 20% of all income earners receive 63% of the nation’s income.
Moreover, the top 10% of all income earners receive 47% of all income. In
the way of a comparison, those same numbers for Canada are 39% and 24%,
respectively, and for the U.S., 46% and 31%, respectively (WDR 2000/2001Table
5). A Bread for the World study revealed that only two percent of the population
own 80% of the land (Bread for the World 1990, p. 80), many of whom live on
estates that average nearly 600 acres (Barry 1992, p. 104). Inequality of this
magnitude cannot help but contribute to unfortunate social outcomes. The average
life expectancy in the country, according to the United Nations, is only 64
years and the infant mortality rate is 41 (deaths per 1000 live births) (UNHDR
2000 Tables 1 and 9). Suzanne Jonas reminds us, however, that the life
expectancy for Guatemala’s indigenous Mayan population is 16 years lower than
for the ladino population[12],
and also that the infant mortality rate is twice as high for the indigenous
population as it is for ladinos (Jonas 1991, p. 179). The adult literacy
rate is an oppressively low 63%—only Haiti is worse, out of all of the Latin
American countries.[13]
32% of the population does not have access to safe water and 40% does not have
access to health services (UNHDR 2000, Tables 1 and 4). The Bread for the World
Study further noted that three quarters of Guatemala’s citizens live in
poverty, with nearly 60% unable to meet minimal nutritional needs. An
astonishing 85% of children under 5 years of age experience malnourishment to
some degree. Stunted growth was observed in up to 95% of non-Spanish speaking
children[14] (Bread for the World
1990, pp. 79-80). It is difficult to see evidence of a rising tide of prosperity
in Guatemala after two decades of pursuing neo-liberal development strategies
except among a privileged few citizens. For the majority, day-to-day living remains a precarious
struggle.
In
stark contrast, there is a community nestled on the southeast shore of Lake
Atitlán in central Guatemala—San Lucas Tolimán—where social indicators are
significantly more hopeful than those of the rest of the country.
This is not the result of luck or good circumstance, but rather the
outcome of a human-first approach to economic development in place now for
nearly four decades. In the early 1960s, San Lucas was a typically poor and
downtrodden highlands community. The hopes that had been temporarily raised
during the brief experiment with democracy under the Arevalo and Arbenz
administrations (1944-54) had faded quickly in the face of a military insurgency
that violently suppressed the reform movement. Approximately 500,000 peasants,
including some in San Lucas, had received land under Jacabo Arbenz’ 1952
Agrarian Reform Law, decree 900. To the beneficiaries, this was long overdue
justice after nearly 500 years of oppression and land grabs, but to the
oligarchy, this was an affront to their privileged way of life—this was
communism. The land, for the most part, was forcibly returned, and so brutal was
the military dictatorship that followed, that it spawned a rebel
counterinsurgency. The rebel forces demanded land, justice, and indigenous
rights, among other things. The country was essentially at war with itself.[15]
It
was in such a volatile environment that the Catholic Diocese of New Ulm,
Minnesota made a commitment to link its parish with that of San Lucas Tolimán
with a permanent mission project.[16] The Diocese provided two
young priests, fresh out of seminary, Father Greg Schaffer (arriving in 1964)
and Father John Goggin (arriving in 1967), to oversee the operation. They
didn’t come armed with fancy degrees in economics, engineering, or business.
They simply arrived full of the social gospel and with ideas about peacemaking
and community building from studying the works of Ghandi, Dorothy Day, and E.F.
Schumacher[17].
San Lucas, at the time, was like many other communities in the central highlands. It was poor, with little infrastructure, little hope, and a distribution of land that heavily favored the coffee-owning oligarchy. The skewed land holding patterns were not accidental. From the arrival of Hernan Cortes’ lieutenant Pedro de Alvarado in 1523 until the present, those in power have arranged the laws of the country to ensure the landed elite a steady supply of seasonal workers. Vagrancy laws, forced labor laws, evictions, threats, and scorched earth military policies have all been used to make sure that the peasantry—mostly Mayan indigenous peoples—are not capable of sustaining themselves for an entire year on their tiny plots of land. When their food supply runs out, they have no choice but to travel long distances to the giant fincas (plantations) at planting or harvest times.
Those
left with no land at all often find themselves with no choice but to live
permanently in stark colonias (worker
colonies) on the edge of the patrón’s
(boss or owner) coffee or sugar plantation in a fashion not unlike the feudal
system of the middle ages. They are therefore available to meet the immediate
needs of the patrón throughout the
year. In exchange, the landowner is
obligated (at least according to the constitution) to provide shelter, water,
healthcare, schooling, and a minimum wage. In practice, the colonias are among the most destitute places on earth, with few
provisions at all. The appearance of the children tell the whole story; most
look like they have never had baths, or a toothbrush, or a change of clothes, or
enough food for a single day of their lives.
You
might think that in an enlightened age in which we supposedly live, early in the
21st century, that such a social/economic arrangement would have
ceased to exist. In fact, it is beginning to crumble, slowly, but unfortunately,
it is happening not because of a general enlightenment, but rather because the patróns
have discovered that it is more profitable to “release” their workers to the
freedom of the marketplace and then hire them back on a seasonal or day-to-day
basis. This sounds like it might
meet some of the criteria associated with economic efficiency discussed earlier,
but if there is no land, jobs, or affordable housing for the workers upon their
“release,” then in many respects, they are worse off with their economic
“freedom,” than they were under the gun of the patrón and his
foremen.
This
was the setting into which Padres Schaffer and Goggin were thrown.
Some of the immediate needs in the community were straightforward and
merely required focused attention, creativity, manpower, and funding. A lack of
schools, water, and health care were among the most pressing, as well as a
problem of how to care for the growing numbers of orphaned children, many of
whom had lost parents to the widening circle of violence and poverty. With
funding from New Ulm, construction on school, church, and orphanage buildings
was begun, teachers were hired, a health clinic staffed with volunteers from the
states was begun, and designs for a pumping system to deliver water from Lake
Atitlán were implemented.
The
people, though, needed more than physical goods and services; they needed hope
and a vision for the future. As Father Greg saw things, the role of the church
was to empower people, rather than to merely save souls. Empowerment would come from addressing not only physical
needs, but spiritual and intellectual needs, as well. Furthermore, empowerment,
as opposed to charity, comes from having control over decisions that affect your
life. Recognizing this, the parish
collaborated with community leaders, establishing the Christian Action
Committee, a group that is involved in all project planning, helping to ensure
that decisions are made from the bottom up—recognizing the needs of the people
first—rather than from the top down.
A
particularly fateful decision was made with the construction of the first church
annex building that would guide all future parish/committee activity.
Rather than use scarce money from contributions to bring in professional
builders and material resources from outside the community, it was decided to
use as many local resources—workers and materials—as possible.
The idea was one right out of the pages of an economics textbook—to
allow locally generated wages and expenditures on materials to multiply
throughout the community to create even greater wealth. With few leakages in the
process to Guatemala City or elsewhere, the local multiplier effect would be
magnified. A local stonemason was found along with a student who taught himself
how to read a blue print. The stonemason pointed out that the region was
abundant with beautiful, high quality volcanic rock and so this material was
chosen for many of the early construction projects.
Paid volunteers for the project learned new skills along the way, which
they were quick to share with others, for along with basic skills, hope and
pride were being learned as well.
Over
the years, this skill building became more formalized in the manner of an
apprenticeship program, thus filling a sizeable gap in the technical and trades
education in the central highlands, since government money for such schools was
virtually nonexistent. There have evolved over the years apprentice programs in
stone masonry, stone cutting, carpentry, welding, plumbing, and electricity,
with master craftsmen and teachers supervising in each area. The process is
streamlined. For example, if someone comes to the parish and asks if he can
learn how to become a stonemason, Father Greg will send him directly to Lucas
Xiruc, the director of the apprentice program, and Lucas will direct him to one
of six building projects that are currently underway and see to it that he
receives training in stone masonry. He
will be paid a wage along the way and eventually be certified to start up his
own operation. There are over 300 individuals who have graduated from the
apprenticeship program over the years who remain in the region running their own
businesses. The apprenticeship program, therefore, results in a constant stream
of skilled workers being channeled into the community.
As
an example of the apprenticeship program and the use of local skills and
resources, a new community hospital was recently completed to address the
burgeoning health care needs of the region. Master craftsmen and apprentices in
all of the above-mentioned categories—stone masonry, construction, plumbing,
etc.—were employed in the general construction. The cinder blocks that were
used in making the walls, for example, came from some of the three-man cement
block fabricas (factories), located throughout town, most of which trace their
origins to the apprenticeship program. There are more technologically efficient
ways of making cement blocks than to use a hand press to be sure, but factories
employing such technology are in distant locations and thus would not make use
of local labor and materials. Another aspect of the construction of the hospital
that can be traced back to earlier decisions to utilize local materials was the
use of bamboo trunks as interior wall studs, rather than purchasing lumber from
Guatemala City at great cost. Bamboo is abundant throughout the region, free of cost, and
just as sturdy as finished lumber, and equally important, the cutting and
preparation is done using local labor.
While
many of the successful parish programs have evolved over the years relying on
the method of trial and error and based on the exigencies of the moment—for
example, if the money doesn’t exist to buy cut lumber, then there is no choice
but to use bamboo—there is, in fact, a theoretical logic behind most of them.
The rationale for the use of local resources comes partly from the writings of
E.F. Schumacher. He notes that the products of sophisticated technology are
“not normally an urgent need of the poor. What the poor need most of all are
simple things—building materials, clothing, household goods, agricultural
implements—and a better return for their agricultural products. They also most
urgently need... trees, water, and crop storage facilities.
Most agricultural populations would be helped immensely if they could
themselves do the first stages of processing their products” (1973, p. 186).
The
parish programs—nearly every single one of them—take Schumacher seriously
and literally. Wherever physically and feasibly possible, as many stages of
processing are done using local resources and workers. The construction of the
hospital, mentioned above, is a perfect example of this approach.
In
addition to the need to maximize the use of local resources, most decisions are
also made with a concern for sustainability. This is a multifaceted concept. In
the broadest sense, it refers to methods of organizing society in ways such that
human activities are carried out within the bounds of the earth’s carrying
capacity.[18] The upper limit of
resources that can be sustained for a region (or possibly for the entire world)
defines its carrying capacity. Theoretically, a sustainable activity could be
pursued forever. An economic system that reserves the majority of all arable
land for the production of chemical intensive export crops such as coffee or
sugar is not sustainable. It is not
sustainable in terms of the impacts on the soil in that ever-increasing
quantities of fertilizers and pesticides need to be applied to maintain harvest
levels. It is not sustainable in terms of the displacement of indigenous peoples
from their lands, who then have no choice but to seek out ever more distant and
disagreeable plots on which to carry out their family farming activities.
Lands that never should never have been cleared for agricultural purposes
such as rainforests or steep hillsides are now laid bare to the negative effects
of erosion and loss of vegetative transpiration. Also, a system that throws
people off their lands and forces them to sell their labor at starvation wages
is not economically sustainable.
To
address the problems of environmental non-sustainability in the region, the
parish committee decided early on to initiate a forestry project. The project
had two goals: 1) to provide lumber for local construction needs—bamboo
isn’t appropriate for all construction needs—and 2) to assist in the
reforestation of the region. Experimentation with crossbreeding over the years
has resulted in a strain of fast growing cypress trees that are capable of
producing mature trees in 15 years. They are either given away or sold at cost
for local building projects and regional reforestation projects.
The program has gained an international reputation over the years and is
occasionally called upon to assist with reforestation projects in other parts of
the world. This is an example of
the modern adage: “think globally, act locally.”
The
inability of the small amount of land to meet the basic needs of the population
was the most vexing of all the many sustainability-related problems facing San
Lucas. The community was hemmed in, in practically every direction; giant coffee
fincas lay to the south and west, Lake Atitlán to the north, and a steep
2000 foot ridge to the east. An
orthodox economist might view such a situation from a distance and claim it to
be Pareto Optimal, in that any redistribution of land would make at least one
person worse off. Also, on the basis of comparative advantage, any such land
reform, it could be argued, would represent an inefficient use of resources and
thus contribute to a reduction of overall economic output. It would not make any
theoretical sense, therefore, to take land that is divided into large enough
tracts to take advantage of what economists refer to as economies of scale[19]
and subdivide it into a lot of little parcels for use as family farms. The
coffee plantations are earning the maximum possible revenues that could be
obtained from such rich, nutritious soil, and to reorganize the land into small
plots of corn, beans, and squash, would be seen as a GDP-minimizing
reallocation.
The
parish committee, not feeling particularly restricted by economic theory,
however, viewed this problem as one with both short-term and long-term
solutions. In the short-run, it was necessary to determine the most efficient
agricultural techniques and highest yielding crops that could be grown on the
limited amount of land in the community. Also,
every possible piece of land that was not otherwise claimed, such as steep
slopes on the sides of the two nearby dormant volcanoes, was considered for
cultivation. Ecologically friendly fruit bearing trees, such as citrus and
avocado, were planted in such locations. Analysis and experimentation was begun
with crop growth rates, different soil compositions, and importantly, with
composting. In the spirit of sustainability, and given limited funding, the
decision was made to avoid expensive chemical fertilizers and pesticides. An
educational program was needed to convince small landholders of newer, and
greener ways of farming. For
example, it was quite a task to convince farmers to not burn off last year’s
corn stalks, but rather to collect them along with other organic roughage and
start compost piles.
Diligence
in this area paid off, as it was discovered that the organic techniques, along
with the 60 inches of rain during the rainy season, could yield as many as two
separate harvests for most crops. Furthermore, with careful attention to
terracing and the construction of seed beds, as many as four separate crops
could be grown on the same amount of land that would normally be used for a
single crop if commercial approaches were used. A typical campesino’s milpa
field is likely to consist of corn (maize), pole beans, bush beans, and
squash. One particular program that grew out of the early experiments with
organic farming continues to provide sustainable futures for local families;
namely the production of export-quality coffee. The small local growers can
never hope to compete with the large fincas in terms of quantity, but
their goal, rather, is to compete on the basis of quality. Coffee grown at the
nearly mile-high elevation on the land surrounding San Lucas, in conjunction
with the rich volcanic soil, is some of the best in the world.
In
order for the program (known as the Juan-Ana Coffee Program[20])
to be a success—where success would be defined as pulling families out of
poverty and offering hope for the future—new ways of thinking were required.
Coffee is not a traditional part of the indigenous culture, though the Mayans
have been exposed to the industry in one way or another ever since its
appearance in Guatemala as a cash crop in the 19th century. Had the
Spaniards and their cash crops never shown up in the highlands, the peasant
farmers would have remained content to this day working their milpa
fields. However, since a typical plot of land is not sufficient to meet most
families’ food needs for a year, coffee production offers an alternative use
for part of that small parcel. The proceeds from the sale of the coffee, thus,
might generate enough income to pay for additional food and for other household
needs such as medicine or tuition for school. A mere half acre devoted to coffee
production may make the difference between health and hunger. Depending on
market prices for coffee, a well managed, half acre plot could generate as much
as $500 US, or significantly more if the family is participating in the Juan-Ana
program.
For
newly participating families in the program, there are the usual complications
one would expect for any new business owner: resource costs, maintenance,
financing, labor, security, processing, transportation, marketing, etc. Only the
highest quality Arabica trees are used. There is the matter of selecting the
right kinds of shade trees to prevent the coffee beans from over-exposure to the
sun. Another issue is the timing
and method of the harvest. Small
owners need to carefully pick only those berries that are ripe.
This may necessitate several passes through the stand of trees during the
harvest season—something that would be considered economically inefficient on
the giant fincas. This is very time and labor intensive, but guaranteed to
maintain high levels of production. The branches from which berries have been
delicately picked will suffer no damage and produce bountiful yields in future
years, unlike those that get stripped clean by day laborers on the fincas who
are paid by the pound. Careful picking also ensures that the 100 lb. bags are
full of ripe berries, rather than hard green berries, sticks, and stems. All of
these are important issues because if the overall program is to be successful,
only the best quality berries will be accepted.
In
addition to offering educational assistance to new farmers in the above areas,
the program offers the services of a beneficio (a processing plant),
where the beans are cleaned and roasted. The beneficio employs a number
of full time employees who, in the spirit of E.F. Schumacher, are engaged in
every single stage of coffee processing, from the initial weighing and cleaning,
to the roasting, packaging, and transporting. The program, in an effort to
address the issue of economic sustainability, offers participating families
above-market prices for their coffee and directly markets the finished product
in the United States, thus eliminating the markup of the middleman.
The
parish consulted with local growers to determine their costs of production and
their family financial needs and arrived at a fixed price of 200Q (approximately
$26 at the current exchange rate: 1.00$ US = 7.75 Quetzals) per 100 lbs. of raw
beans. World market prices may drop
to a quarter of that, but the project holds its payments to the families firm at
200Q. The processed coffee is then marketed in attractive 17 oz bags selling for
just $5.00 in the US from parish offices in New Ulm, Minnesota. At this point,
the sale of the coffee is just covering the costs of the project back in San
Lucas, i.e., it is sustainable. The
growers receive prices that can support their families, the employees at the beneficio
receive a livable wage, and coffee lovers in the US enjoy an earth and
human-friendly cup of quality coffee. At
the moment, there are over 200 families participating in the program, up from
approximately 65 in 1996. Father
Greg anticipates the numbers to grow to over 300 just as soon as a second beneficio,
located on the newly acquired finca El Pornvenir, is reactivated. Success
in accommodating the additional families will also necessitate that the diocese
in New Ulm spread the word of the availability of this quality product farther
and wider among sister parishes in the US. Mainstream advertising is not yet in
the works, though the parish for the past two years has added a holiday mailer
to its newsletter that advertises the coffee as well as locally made crafts.
An
interesting note to this coffee story is that, as most readers are by now aware,
there is a rather serious slump in the world coffee market. The introduction of Vietnamese coffee, encouraged by the
World Bank, has swamped global markets with excess production leading to falling
prices at many of the stages of production. Quetzal prices for raw beans are
expected to fall to as low as 35 or 40Q this harvest season, less than a quarter
of the 200Q the parish is paying its participating farmers.
Lower grade coffee from the coastal region is already starting to sell at
only 20Q, a most ominous sign. While many producers in Guatemala and throughout
the world are facing bankruptcy, the Juan-Ana program is still in good shape. In
previous years when specialty coffee prices brought extremely high prices in
boutique markets—Jamaican Blue Mountain coffee selling for as much as $45 a
pound is one extreme example—many growers jumped on the bandwagon and
increased production significantly and sellers of roasted coffee built the
higher retail prices into their future expectations.
The Juan-Ana program, on the other hand, has kept its retail prices fixed
for nearly a decade at $5.00 per 17 oz. bag and has only accepted families into
the program willing to produce the highest quality coffee.
As retail prices at grocery stores for quality grades of coffee have
fallen from earlier highs of $7-10 per pound toward prices in the vicinity of
$4-7 per pound, the Juan-Ana coffee continues to be competitively priced. As a
result, the program has not been adversely affected by the world slump, and in
fact, as mentioned above, it hopes to expand its coverage to 100 additional
families.
Earlier,
it was suggested that there were both short and long-term solutions to the
various problems facing San Lucas. The long-term aspect of the land problem
required a great deal of patience. Prime agricultural land, like that
surrounding San Lucas, rarely, if ever, becomes available for sale in Guatemala.
Occasionally, however, a family, many generations into the ownership of a farm,
may grow weary of the responsibilities of maintaining the operation. The parish
committee, with its local contacts, keeps a close eye on such affairs and stands
ready to make offers to purchase land on behalf of various groups of families.
There have been a number of successful purchases over the years and no
one single transaction has been identical to another.
A situation that is not atypical, however, involves the purchase of land
for families living on colonias, the tiny residential parcels attached to
the corners of the giant fincas, mentioned earlier.
The following actual case history illustrates the complexity of
Guatemala’s land issues.
A
new patrón took over the finca Santa Teresa in April 1997. He was
a businessman from Guatemala City and was unfamiliar with the long-standing
traditions in many of the coffee fincas whereby the day starts as early
as 4:00 or 5:00 AM with work concluding by mid-day, at which point the laborers
retire to their own tiny plots to tend their crops.
This arrangement had been in place for generations producing high yields
of export quality coffee for the previous patrón and allowing a
subsistence lifestyle for the workers and their families.
The new owner was of the opinion that a full workday consisted of early
morning to early evening hours, such as was the case in the factories in the
city. Furthermore, he felt that the
workers needed to increase their daily workload, or tarea, by a factor of
five. At this point in the work
cycle, they were applying limestone fertilizer to the trees.
He felt that they should increase their tarea from 100 to 500 lbs.
of fertilizer.
To
the workers, these were impossible demands.
In addition to the unbearable physical strain of carrying four additional
100 lb. bags of limestone up the hillsides, there was a second and even more
serious matter. By having their
workday extended into the evening, this would reduce or possibly eliminate the
time they could spend farming their own little parcels. One cannot overemphasize
the critical nature of these plots. As small as they are, they provide the
additional food that their meager wages are not capable of buying. Access to
them in many cases literally determines life or death.
The workers’ protests over the new demands fell on deaf and uncaring ears, and, in fact, since the patrón was used to dealing with perfectly subordinate workers, he responded to their defiance with vengeance. They were ordered to leave the property. One hundred families with ties to the land extending over many generations were given two days to pack their belongings and depart.
Fortunately
for these families, Father John Goggin had been visiting them over the years as
part of his ministry to the outlying aldeas (rural communities
surrounding San Lucas) and he was made aware of their plight. The presence of a
small parcel of land near a sugar plantation that the families might move to and
that was available for purchase was brought to the attention of the parish
committee and an agreement was signed. This
was only a temporary arrangement, however. The land was hardly suitable for a
permanent stay. In addition to
being too small for 100 families, it was of questionable agricultural quality.
A search for a larger parcel of land ensued, vigorous fund raising began
back in the US, and eventually two impressive estates were identified that had
come on the market and they were purchased at a cost of approximately $450,000.
The families’ occupation of the new land is taking place in stages.
One
of the two parcels was better suited for agriculture.
On this site there is sufficient water and high quality soil for
extensive farming, though much work lies ahead even two and a half years after
the August 1998 closing of the purchase. Part of the property had been a coffee finca,
but had been long since abandoned. This section of the land will require extensive care and
attention, and probable replanting of a majority of the trees. On the remainder
of the property, as it gets cleared section by section, plans are under way for
vegetable gardens, bean, and corn fields, as well as a number of spices,
flowers, and Spanish Cedar trees. There are high hopes that the cedar trees will
thrive on the new parcel because they bring a good price in export markets.
The
other parcel, which is detached from the agricultural site, will be the location
for housing, as well as a soccer field. While
the agricultural site is aggressively being cleared and farmed, the preparation
of the second site for housing has been significantly delayed because of water
source problems, mainly of a legal nature. These problems have only recently
been resolved, thus allowing work on the retention tanks at the water source to
begin. I was in San Lucas back in August (2001) and accompanied Andres Chajil,
the water project manager, for a day of work at the nacimientos (the
water sources) several miles up-slope from the housing parcel. I was using the
trusty chronometer feature on my runners watch to measure the rate of water flow
from each of the three springs. After making the conversion from the number of
seconds it took to fill a five-gallon bucket to the more usable measure of
gallons per minute and announcing my findings, Andres broke into a big smile. He
announced that the water flow was clearly acceptable for supporting the housing
project. His next words were simply, “This is good. Water is life.” He gave
a chuckle at having made such a profound statement, and with that, we packed up
our tools and headed back to the parish to report the good news.
Until
Andres and his work crews can connect the water pipes to the retention tanks and
run them to the housing plot, the families will continue to live on the tiny
parcel next to the sugar plantation and commute each day to their new farm.
The parish is paying the workers a daily wage for their efforts until
they are firmly ensconced on their property. The construction and financing of
the houses will likely take place in a manner similar to previous land deals.
The new owners, for example, will offer their collective sweat equity,
much like the process with Habitat for Humanity homes in the US. Any costs, such as building materials that can’t come
straight from the land, will be financed through the parish with long-term
loans.
There
is an ancient Mayan saying that aptly expresses the feelings of the 100 families
as they move ahead in their new venture of independence: “Tortillas made from
corn we grow on our own land taste better.” For the first time in their lives,
there is a sense of hope for these people.
The daughter of one of the families was asked by a visiting American,
“How do you like it here?” Her
response was an enthusiastic, “My mom and dad are happy because this is our
own.”
Bringing
hope to families is probably the best measure of success for any economic
development program. In stark contrast to the gloomy statistics on social
welfare for Guatemala, the citizens of San Lucas appear to be faring much
better, thanks to the parish related programs. To an unprepared visitor, the
people of San Lucas would appear desperately poor, at least by US standards.
By Guatemalan standards, however, or by the standards of communities in
other developing countries, one would have to conclude that progress has been
made in a number of areas. The
apprentice program mentioned earlier is a good example of such progress.
There
has also been remarkable progress in education. Parish-related schools educate
600 students per year, many of whom attend at least through 6th
grade. They employ over 50 teachers, many teaching in the outlying colonias
or aldeas. There are 17 elementary schools serving the metropolitan area,
all but two of which the parish had a direct hand in creating. Back in 1963 there was only a single public school. As the
parish schools have flourished over the years, reaching out to ever more distant
communities, the government has stepped into the picture to assist with funding.
Most highlands communities are lucky to have a single functioning school, much
less 17. A study in the early 1990s found that San Lucas Tolimán had a literacy
rate of 85%, which is an amazing statistic for a highlands community.
I
was lucky enough to be able to attend an elementary school class near the
community of Godenes. The teacher appeared highly qualified—over qualified
possibly—and offered the students a vibrant lesson in math and Mayan culture.
The students were eager to participate and seemed highly motivated. They
became especially animated when the math section ended and the discussion
shifted to the subject of their Mayan heritage. This is a topic that never would
have been allowed in the past—it would have been considered subversive. This
was another sign of progress.
Visible
progress has been made in the provision of medical services. Health care is
available through the clinic and new hospital at little or no cost—no one is
turned away. The metropolitan area is served by 6 full time doctors, 3 full time
dental technicians, and 17 nurses or nurse practitioners. Most use the parish
facilities or in some manner are linked to the parish’s health programs. The
area would benefit from additional health care providers to be sure, but vast
strides have been made since 1963 when there was essentially no medical care
except that provided by local curanderos (the equivalent of medicine men
or women).
Finally, over the last four decades, approximately 2,100 families have received property through parish efforts at locating and purchasing available land, such as the example of the 100 families of Santa Teresa. If one assumes an average family size of six, this means that over 12,000 formerly landless people, out of a population of only 20,000 in San Lucas proper, or 40,000, if the surrounding aldeas are included, have received land. This is a rather impressive accomplishment. On a percentage basis, the parish’s land assistance program has been even more successful than Arbenz’ agrarian reform program in the 1950s.
Economic
theory, as embodied in noble goals like efficiency and growth, offers hope to
all the people of the world according to the principles textbooks.
These goals are at the core of international development programs
administered by the World Bank and IMF, for example. Sometimes though, when
economic theory collides with human reality, the results can be disastrous, as
evidenced by the disturbing statistics from Nicaragua, Ghana, or the 100 or so
countries of the developing world most of which are aggressively pursuing
export-led, neo-liberal economic strategies, as shown in the empirical section
of this study. The disaster that
befell the people of the colonia Santa Teresa in the section above on
Guatemala is an example of what happens when decisions are made only on the
basis of economic efficiency and profit maximization.
Occasionally,
there are development efforts by groups, institutions, or communities that
culminate in programs such as those of the parish of San Lucas Tolimán that are
capable of uplifting, empowering, and providing hope to people like those of the
colonia Santa Teresa. Such programs are successful, though, specifically
because they avoid a dogmatic adherence to theory—a one-size-fits-all
approach. They certainly don’t draw upon the tired notions of socialism, which
would be heavily frowned upon by the authorities in a country like Guatemala.
Rather, the programs described in the previous section on San Lucas Tolimán,
upon close inspection, look a lot like capitalism. “Capitalism with a small
c,” however, is how Father Greg Schaffer and I prefer to think of them. They
rely upon basic human drives to own a piece of property and to be able to make
decisions that affect one’s life’s outcomes. They are based on hard work, a
spirit of community, and a love of life. In fact, the programs’ success
clearly depends upon the capitalist assumptions of rationality and the primacy
of individual initiative. The designation “capitalism with a small c” comes
from the emphasis on local needs and resources, rather than an embracing of the
neo-liberal version of global capitalism. Adam Smith was apparently interested
in “capitalism with a small c” as well. In the famous passage from the Wealth
of Nations where he introduces the concept of the invisible hand of the
marketplace mentioned earlier, he makes specific reference to the primacy of
domestic over foreign industry. “By preferring the support of domestic
(emphasis added) to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security;
and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the
greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is…led by an invisible
hand to promote an end (the betterment of society as a whole) which was no part
of his intention” (2000, pp. 484-5).
David
Korten, author of When Corporations Rule the World, approaches this issue
even more emphatically. Addressing what he sees as a global crisis of deepening
poverty, social disintegration, and environmental destruction, all of which are
problematic in Guatemala, he states, “Solutions require local
action—household by household and community by community. This action can be
taken only when local resources are in local hands. The most pressing unmet
needs of the world’s people are for food security, adequate shelter, clothing,
health care, and education—the lack of which defines true deprivation. With
rare exception, the basic resources and capacity to meet these needs are already
found in nearly every country. The natural inclination of local people is
usually to give these needs priority. If, however, control lies elsewhere,
different priorities usually come into play (2001, p. 31).
The programs of San Lucas Tolimán are designed specifically with Korten’s assumptions in mind. The community has learned over the years that there are no individuals or institutions—not the Guatemalan government, not the US government, and not the IMF or World Bank—who understand its problems, appreciate its problems, and who can devise solutions better than its own citizens. The positive outcomes of four decades of community-oriented development might alert the official world of economics that there are useful alternatives to neo-liberal, outward-looking, export-oriented policies. And I suspect that Adam Smith would agree whole-heartedly.
Abell, John. (1997). “Peace in Guatemala? The Story of
San Lucas Tolimán.” In Brauer, Jurgen and Gissy, William. Economics of
Conflict and Peace. Aldershot, England: Avebury.
Asher, Herbert. (1983). Causal Modeling 2nd
ed. Beverly Hills, California: Sage Publications.
Barnet, Richard, and Müller, Ronald. (1974). Global
Reach. New York: Touchstone, Simon and Schuster.
Beazley, Mitchell. (1993). Caring For The Earth.
London, England: Reed International Books Ltd.
Byrns, Ralph, and Stone, Gerald. (1992). Economics 5th
ed. New York: Harper Collins.
Case, Karl, and Fair, Ray. (2002). Principles of
Economics 6th ed. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
Frank, Robert, and Bernanke, Ben. (2001). Principles of
Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin.
George, Susan. (1990). A Fate Worse Than Debt. New
York: Food First, Grove Weidenfeld.
Handy, Jim (1984). Gift of the Devil: A History of
Guatemala. Boston, Massachusetts: South End Press.
Handy, Jim. (1994). Revolution in the Countryside: Rural
Conflict and Agrarian Reform in Guatemala, 1944-1954. Chapel Hill, North
Carolina: The University of North Carolina Press.
Korten, David. (1995). When Corporations Rule the World.
West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian Press.
Korten, David. (1999). The Post-Corporate World.
West Hartford, Connecticut: Kumarian Press.
McEachern, William. (2000). Economics 5th
ed. Cincinnati, Ohio: South-Western.
Ricardo, David. (1966). The Principles of Political
Economy and Taxation. London: Cambridge University Press.
Rodney, Walter. (1982). How Europe Underdeveloped Africa.
Washington DC: Howard University Press.
Rostow, Walter. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A
Non-Communist Manifesto. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Samuelson, Paul, and Nordhaus, William. (1992). Economics
14th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Schumacher, E.F. (1975). Small Is Beautiful: Economics
as if People Mattered. New York: Perennial Library.
Sexton, Robert. (1999). Exploring
Macroeconomics. Orlando, Florida: Dryden Press.
Smith, Adam. (2000). The Wealth of Nations. New
York: The Modern Library.
United Nations Human Development Report 2000. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Wilber, Charles (Ed.). (1988). The Political Economy
of Development and Underdevelopment, 4th ed., New York: Random
House.
World Bank World Development Report 2000/2001. New
York: Oxford University.
Younger, Mary Sue. (1979). A Handbook for Linear Regression. Belmont, California: Duxbury Press, Wadsworth.
[1] The Merriam-Webster Dictionary (1974).
[2] Economists and policy makers are specifically concerned with inflation adjusted GDP, otherwise known as Real GDP, or constant dollar GDP.
[3] Adam Smith discussed at some length the concepts of free trade and comparative advantage in the Wealth of Nations, see (2000, p. 487) for example, but it is David Ricardo whose name is most often associated with these concepts.
[4] There is a difference between comparative advantage and absolute advantage. Absolute advantage is the ability of one country to out-produce another country. In the above example, Guatemala has a comparative advantage over the US in the production of bananas and coffee because it can produce them at a lower per-unit cost than the US. Suppose that the US attempted to out-produce Guatemala (i.e., gain an absolute advantage) using an extensive system of climate-controlled greenhouses, with chemical fertilizers and pesticides. The theory of comparative advantage would view such an effort as inefficient and wasteful—it would definitely not be the least cost way of producing bananas and coffee. Even if it were technically possible to create an absolute advantage in such a manner, the theory of comparative advantage would still suggest that each country specialize in producing those items they can produce at least (per-unit) cost and then engage in trade.
[5] For more on the impacts of
structural adjustment on Nicaragua, see A High Price To Pay: Structural Adjustment and Women in Nicaragua, a
Witness For Peace publication, 1996.
[6] For more on this, see Wilber, Charles and Kenneth Jameson, “Paradigms of Economic Development and Beyond,” (pp. 3-27), in Wilber (1988).
[7] See Susan George (1990) for a discussion of the failure of recycled petro-dollars in the 1980s to be used effectively for the building of wealth producing structures in developing countries.
[8] An externality is an extra cost of doing business for which companies refuse to take responsibility, and which society therefore must bear. The outbreak of Spina Bifida among newborn babies in Mexican border towns in the 1990s due to toxic dumping by foreign chemical companies is an example of this problem.
[9] See Asher (1983, p. 12).
[10] The significance of the correlation coefficient is based on the following t statistic: . This statistic follows the t-distribution with n-2 degrees of freedom. Calculated t statistics for each correlation coefficient are available upon request.
[11] This is the subtitle of E.F. Schumacher’s book, Small is Beautiful (1973).
[12] According to Jim Handy (1984), “Ladino refers to people of mixed blood and western culture, and is also used in Guatemala to refer to Indians who have adopted western costume and culture” (p. 14).
[13] I don’t use the descriptive expression for Guatemala’s literacy rate, “oppressively low,” lightly or for sensational purposes. When a country selectively educates only a portion of its population, it is relegating those left out to a lifetime of oppression. When you can’t read or write, you have no idea if you are being cheated when you sign a work contract or when you sign a document related to your property. You are never sure of your civil rights or how to seek redress if you suspect they have been violated. In short, you are permanently relegated to second-class citizenship.
[14] There are 22 distinct Mayan peoples and languages in Guatemala. It is not safe to assume that in Mayan communities Spanish is spoken or even understood. Depending on the estimate, it is thought that the Mayans constitute as much as 60% of the overall population.
[15] For an analysis of the revolution of 1944-54, see Jim Handy, Revolution in the Countryside (1994).
[16] For an analysis of the evolution of the parish programs of San Lucas Tolimán and the role they played in helping the community to avoid the worst of the violence during Guatemala’s civil war, see Abell (1997). The information in this section on San Lucas is drawn from unpublished parish archival material and personal interviews and observations.
[17] Schumacher’s famous book Small is Beautiful: Economics As If People Mattered was nearly a decade away from publication at this point, but Father Greg had already heard of his writings and had spoken with him at length at a seminar on his ideas about the importance of locally-oriented economies.
[18] For more on the concept of sustainability and carrying capacity, see Beazley, M. Caring for the Earth (1993), pp.10-13.
[19] Economies of scale refers to the phenomenon of falling costs associated with larger sized operations. A large firm could take advantage of volume discounts on purchases of inputs that might not be available to a small firm, for example.
[20] Named after Father Greg’s father and mother.
*The author wishes to give thanks to Melissa Abell and Elizabeth Perry for reading and commenting on earlier drafts of this paper. Travel to Guatemala for observations and interviews was funded by a Davidson Grant from Randolph-Macon Woman’s College.